Title: Cooperation Coordination and Competition in Supply Chain
1Cooperation Coordination and Competition in
Supply Chain
- Prof. Yehuda Bassok
- Marshall Scholl of Business
- University of Southern California
2Agenda
- What is new
- What are the problems
- Some solutions
- Supply Contracts
- Negotiation
3What is the problem?
- Supply chains are composed of many players
- The objectives and interests of the different
players are different. Resulting in each player
pulling the wagon in a different direction and
creating inefficiencies in the supply chain. - Examples
- Production quantities
- Allocation of profits
4What is the problem?
- Harry Potter magic spells losses for booksellers
- Millions of people will descend on stores for a
copy of "Harry Potter and the Deathly Hallows" in
July, but deep discounts mean many will struggle
to turn a profit from the jamboree. - "Everywhere you go there is huge, ridiculous
discounting by the chains," said Graham Marks,
children's editor at the British-based trade
magazine Publishing News. - "They are literally not going to make one penny
out of the book. It is stupid -- just throwing
money away ... The world has gone mad."
5What is the problem?
6What is the objective?
- Coordinate the channel
- What do we mean by channel coordination?
- Profits of the different players in the channel
are Pareto optimal. That is it is impossible to
increase the profits of a player without
decreasing the profit of another one. - When the channel is not coordinated it is
possible to improve the profits of some players
without hurting the others. In this case no one
should be against the change.
7Channel Coordination
Utility of player B
A
F
B
Utility of player A
d
8What are the reasons for the channel not being
coordinated?
- Lack of information
- Information about the demand is not transmitted
up stream. - Conflicting interest
- Retailers would like to have daily deliveries
- Daily deliveries are expensive for the suppliers
- Manufacturers would like to have a stable
production environment. - Buyers would like to have the flexibility to
adjust to the demand and change orders with a
short notice.
9Information Sharing
- Lack of demand visibility is usually considered
as a major challenge for efficient management of
supply chains - Demand distortion (bullwhip effect)
- The variability in the demand is increasing as we
move up-stream at the supply chain. - Was observed by Proctor Gamble making diapers.
10The supply chain
- Retailer
- Distributor
- Wholesaler
- Manufacturer
- Flow of goods
Customer
Retailer
Wholesaler
Distributor
Manufacturer
11The supply chain
- Transportation Delay
- Two period delay
R. Orders
D. Orders
W. Orders
Customer
Retailer
Wholesaler
Distributor
Manufacturer
12 13Information Sharing The bullwhip effect
14Information Sharing The bullwhip effect
- Demand distortion leads to
- High variability in the demand
- Low capacity utilization
- High inventory levels
- Poor availability
- High production cost
- High total cost
15Information Sharing Example
- Wall-mart
- Vendor Managed Inventory System (VMI) An
arrangement in which the vendor monitors the
customers inventory and takes responsibility for
the timing and quantity of replenishments - The vendor has access to selling information
through data rather than to orders. - Proctor Gamble
- Wrangler
- GE
16Information Sharing Example
- Wall-Mart transmit daily information of sales and
inventory to the vendors - Wall-Mart does not place the orders
- The vendor decides the timing and quantity of
each order to warehouses and stores. - Service level went up from 85 to 98
- Reduction in average inventory
- Large scale collaborations are very rare.
- Why?
17Information Sharing Example
- What are the reasons for the improvements?
- Information is valuable and helps in the
production planning and logistics processes - Competition plays an important role.
- In some variant of VMI the improvement is due to
the elimination of the double marginalization
effect.
18Information Sharing
- Reasons for not sharing information
- Trust
- Sales information is a tool in the negotiation
process. - Cost of technology
- Is it possible to coordinate the channel without
sharing information?
19Double Marginalization
- Imagine a supply chain in which
- The manufacturer production cost is 1
- The manufacturer sells the product (whole sale
price) for 5 - The retailer sells the product for 10
- The manufacturer margin is 5 - 1 4
- The retailer margin is 10 5 5
- The channel margin is 10 - 1 9
Double Marginalization
20Double Marginalization
- What is the problem with Double Marginalization?
- Assuming random demand
- From a system point of view (maximizing the
profit of the system) it is optimal to produce a
large quantity - From the retailer point of view it is optimal to
produce a small quantity.
21Double Marginalization Example
- Assume that the demand is either
- 100 units with 0.6 probability
- 200 units with 0.4 probability.
- It is optimal for the retailer to order 100 units
- Profit retailer -5100 10100 500
- Profit manufacturer 1005 1100 400
- Profit channel 500 400 900
- It is optimal for the system to order 200 units
- Profit retailer -5200 0.610000.42000400
- Profit manufacturer -200 1000 800
- Profit channel 1200
22Channel Coordination
Utility of player B
A1200
F900
B1200
Utility of player A
d
23Double Marginalization Question
- Can the problem of double marginalization be
solved? - The retailer optimizes its own profits and at
the same time he orders the channel coordinating
quantity. - Will such a solution benefit all the players
(retailer and manufacturer)?
24Double Marginalization Solution
- Suppose the manufacture is willing to buy back
all leftover inventory for 5. - Retailer profit(2000) -5200
0.6(101005100) 0.42000 700 - Manufacturer profit(2000) -200 2005
-0.61005 500 - Channel profit(2000) 1200
- Is this the best the channel can do?
- Is this the only solution?
- Is it always possible to coordinate the channel?
- What did we learn?
25Double Marginalization Discussion
- In the previous example we assumed that the buy
back price is 5 (r w) - How is the buyback and whole sale prices are
determined? - The buyback and wholesale prices are determined
by negotiation. - Example
- Suppose w 4 and the buyback price is 3.33
- Is this better?
- Is it better for whom?
26Double Marginalization Solution
- Suppose the manufacture is willing to buy back
all the leftover for 3.33. The whole sale price
is 4. - Retailer profit -4200 0.6(10100
3.33100) 0.42000 800 - Manufacturer profit -200 2004 -0.61003.33
400 - Channel profit 1200
- The retailer benefits from the new prices.
- The manufacturer loses from the new prices
- The channel is indifferent
27Double Marginalization Solution
- There are infinite number of pairs (wholesale
and buyback prices) that coordinate the channel. - Which pair is chosen?
- Determined by negotiation
28Definition of negotiation
- Definition Two (or more) players have to divide
a fixed surplus (cost)
29Double Marginalization Negotiation
- The total additional profit (the pie) can be
allocated in many different ways - Example In our case the pie is 300.
- Nash bargaining solution is
-
Negotiation power Of player 1.
Share of player 1
Disagreement point of player 1
30The Pie
- How is the pie allocated?
31Double Marginalization Negotiation
- Taking derivative we get
- Notice that
- Each player has an incentive to inflate the
disagreement points - How do we know what the negotiation power is?
- What ever the negotiation power is it is always
better to coordinate the channel.
32Double Marginalization Negotiation
- Example
- Suppose a 0.5
- d1 d2 0
- Pie 300
- Each player gets an additional profit of 150
- Retailer gets 650
- Manufacturer gets 550
- It is possible to calculate the wholesale price
and buy back so it is the best interest of the
retailer to coordinate the channel and order 200
units.
33Negotiation in Assembly Systems
- A single assembler
- Single period problem
- The assembler faces random demand (demand
distribution is known) for the final products - To assemble one unit of the final product the
assembler needs N different components. - Each component is purchased from one of the N
different suppliers. - Perfect information
34Negotiation in assembly systems
- What are the effects of bargaining on the supply
chain structure. - Which supply chain structure are favorable to
suppliers or retailers?
Assembler
Assembler
Distributor
Suppliers
35The assembly problem
- Decisions
- How many components to purchase from each
supplier? - How much to pay each of the suppliers, or how to
allocate the pie? - How to coordinate the channel, or how to maximize
the size of the pie? - With whom to align, or what is the structure of
the supply chain?
36The Sequential Bargaining Model
- How to extend the basic bargaining model to a
bargaining model in which the assembler
negotiates with N suppliers? - The assembler negotiates simultaneously with the
suppliers - The assembler negotiates sequentially with the
suppliers - Does the sequence of negotiating matter?
- How is the negotiation sequence determined?
37The Sequential Bargaining Model Stage 1
- What is the disagreement point of each of the
players? - At the second sub-stage of the assembler
negotiates with the supplier 2. The size of the
pie, at this stage, must be larger than cA c2
cA,2 - At the first sub-stage the assembler must ensure
that he gets at least cA,2. - At the first sub-stage we solve the following
problem
cA,2
c2
38The Sequential Bargaining Model Stage 1
- The assembler gets 70 (to be allocated further
with the second supplier). The effective profit
of both players is 70 40 30. - Supplier 1 gets 50. His effective profit is 50
20 30. - At the second sub-stage the assembler negotiates
with supplier 2. - The size of the pie is only 70
- At the second stage we solve the following
problem - The effective profits of player 2 and of the
assembler are 15 each
39The Sequential Bargaining Model (Revenue) Stage 1
120
50
70
Supplier 1
Assembler and supplier 2
Sub-stage 1
45
25
Sub-stage 2
Supplier 2
Assembler
40The Sequential Bargaining Model (Profit) Stage 1
60
30
30
Supplier 1
Assembler and supplier 2
Sub-stage 1
15
15
Sub-stage 2
Supplier 2
Assembler
41The Sequential Bargaining Model Stage 1
- The effective profits of the suppliers are not
identical. - Are the effective profits of the players a
function of bargaining sequence? - If player 2 negotiates first then the effective
profit of the assembler is 15, player 1 is 15
and player 2 is 30. - The bargaining sequence does not affect the
effective profits of the assembler. - The bargaining sequence affects the profits of
the suppliers. - Suppliers prefer to negotiate as early as
possible.
42The Sequential Bargaining Model Stage 2
- What is the reaction of the suppliers and the
assembler to such an allocation? - The suppliers will compete, by paying the
assembler, for a better position in the
bargaining sequence. - There is a unique Nash equilibrium in the
effective profits Each of the suppliers gets ¼
of the effective pie. The assembler gets ½ of
the pie.
43The Sequential Bargaining Model Stage 2
- The assembler is using his ability to determine
the negotiation sequence to extract more profit.
Effective profit of the first supplier
Effective profit of the assembler
Effective profit of the second supplier
44The Sequential Bargaining Model Stage 3
- Could the suppliers retaliate to increase their
share of the effective profit? - Suppose the two suppliers form a single coalition
to negotiate with the assembler. - In this case the effective pie is allocated in
the following way ½ to the assembler and ½ to
the coalition (two suppliers). - By forming a coalition the suppliers did not
improve their position. - Is this always true?
- The answer depends on the negotiation power of
the different parties.
45The Sequential Bargaining Model The Effects of
Bargaining Power
- Conclusions
- When the assembler is weak then it is the best
interest of the suppliers to form a coalition. - When the supplier are strong it is the best
interest of the suppliers to negotiate as
independent entities.
46The Sequential Bargaining Model The Effects of
Bargaining Power
- Generalization
- Suppose there are N suppliers.
- Theorem 1 When aA the only stable formation.
- Theorem 2 When aA (0.5)1/(N-2) then the
formation 1,2N is the only stable
formation. - Theorem 3 When 1/N1,2,,N is stable. The grand coalition is
also stable. -
47Coalitions Formations and Stability
- What is a stable coalition formation?
- No coalition defects from a stable formation.
- Far sighted A coalition may defect from a
formation even though myopically some or all its
member lose by defecting. But by defecting from
the formation the coalition triggers a sequence
of defection so that eventually each member of
the defecting coalition benefits.
48Supply contract
- Key elements of a typical supply contract include
- a) capacity, the resources the supplier agrees to
dedicate to the manufacture of the buyer's
components--that is, dedication of manufacturing
lines - b) flexibility, the fluctuation in the buyer's
demand that the supplier is willing to
accommodate at no extra cost
49What is flexibility?
- We discuss two types of flexibility
- The flexibility to update previous commitments
- The flexibility to purchase quantities that
deviate from previously made commitments.
50Information Sharing and Supply Contracts
- An agreement between the buyer and the supplier
- The buyer commits to periodical purchasing
quantities - The supplier provides flexibility to deviate from
the committed quantities.
51Supply Contracts Flexibility
- Flexibility commitments
- The buyer makes a commitment to purchase every
period a certain quantity q1,,qN. - At period 1 the buyer can purchase any quantity
between (1-fL)q1 and (1fH)q1 - In addition, the buyer may update the previous
commitments in the following way q1,2 must be
between (1-f2,L)q2 and (1f2,H)q2 - Similar adjustments are made for all other periods
52Supply Contracts Flexibility
Q
New forecast at period 1
Flexibility
1
53Flexibility Example
- A buyer make a commitment to purchase every month
1000 units. - Suppose
- f1 3
- f12 4
- f13 4
- f14 5
54Flexibility Example
- At the beginning of the first month (January) the
buyer may purchase any quantity between 970 and
1030. - In addition he may update the order quantity for
the second month to any quantity between 960 and
1040. Suppose he chooses 1040. - For the third period (March) he can do the same
- For April he may chose any quantity between 950
and 1050.
55Flexibility Example
- At the beginning of the second month a new round
of commitment updates is conducted. - The supplier may purchase any quantity between
971040 and 1031040 - He may update in the same fashion the previously
made commitments.
56Supply Contracts
- What are the advantages of such contracts?
- What is the value of flexibility?
- How much flexibility do we need?
57Supply Contracts
- The trade-offs for the buyer and the supplier are
clear - the supplier usually incurs additional cost by
providing flexibility, because of the need for
additional production capacity and/or inventory
of raw materials and finished components to meet
the buyer's uncertain demand in a timely manner.
58Supply Contracts
- Owing to the higher flexibility, the buyer is
able to meet, with greater probability, the
uncertain demand and thus realize savings. - It is important to notice that although providing
flexibility is costly for the supplier, the
benefits for the buyer may be high enough that
the total system (supplier and buyer) realizes
savings. -
59Supply Contracts
- These savings may be allocated between the
supplier and the buyer so that both benefit and
realize savings due to the high flexibility in
the system. - As a means of allocating the savings due to
flexibility, the supplier may be willing to offer
different levels of flexibility at appropriate
costs to the buyer.
60Supply Contracts
- It is important to remember that as time passes
and more information is collected, the buyer has
the flexibility to change his or her previously
made commitments. - but this flexibility is limited. The magnitude
of the flexibility is greater for periods further
away. - The reason is the further away the period is,
the more times the commitments may be updated.
This captures the notion that once the supplier
begins to produce the component, the supplier can
offer very limited flexibility.
61Supply Contracts
- On the other hand, the supplier has a
considerably greater flexibility dealing with
orders to be delivered in the distant future. - In many instances, suppliers are unable or
unwilling to provide very large long-term
flexibility in such instances, they limit the
sum of the changes that may be made by the buyer.
62Supply Contracts
- It is possible to provide information of the
following type - The buyer might be willing to pay 41.7 per
unit (instead of 40) in order to have purchase
and update flexibilities of 0.2. - Any cost higher than 41.7 per unit would make it
not worthwhile for the buyer to receive
flexibilities of 0.2. - This cost is referred to here as break-even
cost. As intuition would suggest, the higher the
variability, the higher the worth of flexibility.
63Supply Contracts Case
- Two different supply contracts are evaluated and
compared. - Old Contract (currently in place) have
- a horizon of six months and provide the
following flexibility - The buyer may change the size of previously made
orders to be delivered three, four, five, and six
months in the future by no more than 20 (
0.2). - The size of the orders to be delivered one or two
months in the future cannot be changed ( 0).
64Supply Contracts Case
- New Contract in which
- orders to be delivered in the next period have
an update flexibility of 30 ( 0.3), - orders to be delivered two periods in the future
have 50 update flexibility ( 0.5). - Orders to be delivered three, four, five, and
six months in the future have a very high update
flexibility ( close to 1).
65Supply Contracts Case
- It is clear why the Company found the new
contract more attractive than the old one. - The suppliers preferred the old contract. In the
negotiation process between the buyer and the
supplier, it is crucial to understand and know
the exact worth of the additional flexibility in
the new contract.