Title: New policy guidance on European merger control
1 - New policy guidance on European merger control
- Dr Johannes Luebking
- Deputy Head of Merger Control
- Communication, Information, Media
- DG Competition
- The views expressed are personal to the speaker
2Guidelines on non-horizontal mergers
3Non-horizontal mergers General principles
- No presumption of legality of non-horizontal
mergers. Balance of probabilities standard
applies. - Non-horizontal mergers are generally less likely
to create competition concerns than horizontal
mergers - no loss of direct competition between the merging
parties - possible complementarity of merging parties
- Scope for efficiencies, incl. pricing
efficiencies (elimination of double mark-ups
Cournot effect) - however, there are circumstances in which
non-horizontal mergers may change the ability and
incentive to compete on the part of the merging
company and the competitors in ways that cause
harm to consumers - Convincing evidence required to support finding
of harm - Particularly important when chains of cause
and effect are dimly discernible, uncertain and
difficult to establish (Tetra, par 44)
4Market share andconcentration levels
- No threat to effective competition unless the
merged entity has significant market power, which
does not necessarily amount to dominance, in at
least one of the markets concerned. - Safe harbours
- Commission unlikely to identify competition
concerns when in each of the markets concerned - Market share merged entity
- HHI
- (Except where certain special circumstances are
present which make market shares / HHI less
informative) - No presumption of illegality above the safe
harbours. Need for a case by case assessment.
5Vertical mergers theories of harm
- Non-coordinated effects
- Main concern foreclosure
- any instance where actual or potential rivals
access to supplies or markets is hampered or
eliminated as a result of the merger, thereby
reducing these companies ability and/or
incentive to compete and harming consumers as a
consequence (par 18) - Two forms
- Input foreclosure
- Customer foreclosure
- Other non-coordinated effects
- Access to sensitive information regarding rivals
upstream or downstream activities - Co-ordinated effects
6Analytical framework
- Commission will examine
- Ability to foreclose
- Incentive to foreclose
- Likely impact on effective competition
-
7 Example Input foreclosure
Efficiencies?
Raising rivals costs?
? Net effect on consumers ?
8 (i) Ability to foreclose
- Necessary conditions for the merged entity to
have the ability to foreclose - the input must be important (e.g. in cost or
technology terms) - merged entity must have market power upstream
- E.g. other upstream rivals are less efficient,
offer less preferred alternatives, cannot expand
easily - Input foreclosure may also expose downstream
rivals to independent upstream suppliers with
increased market power - Check possible counter-strategies of downstream
rivals
9(ii) Incentive to foreclose
- Incentive depends on the degree of profitability
of the foreclosing practice - Merged entity faces possible trade-off between
- profit loss due to no longer supplying to
downstream rivals and - profit gain due to expanding sales downstream
and/or being able to raise price in that market - Incentive to foreclose may be higher in case
- Profits upstream are low (compared with
downstream) - Possibility to expand downstream high
- Merged entity has high market share downstream
10Ilegality as a disincentive
- Obligation to examine unlawfulness of conduct as
a disincentive - The Commission has to examine both the incentives
of the merging parties to adopt a conduct and the
factors liable to reduce, or even eliminate,
those incentives, including the possibility that
the conduct is unlawful. - That appraisal, however, does not require an
exhaustive and detailed examination of the rules
of the various legal orders which might be
applicable and of the enforcement policy
practised within them. (Tetra pars 75-78) - Elements that the Commission will take into
account, on the basis of a summary analysis, to
assess whether the illegality of a conduct is
likely to significantly disincentive the merged
entity (par 44) - (i) likelihood that the conduct would be
clearly, or highly probably, unlawful, - (ii) likelihood that the conduct could be
detected, and - (iii) the penalties which could be imposed.
- Examples
- GDP/ENI/EDP EON/MOL
- Thales/Finmecanica
11(iii) Likely impact on effective competition
- Effect impede effective competition in the
downstream market - Merger may raise rivals costs (e.g. increase
input prices) thereby causing an upward pressure
on rivals prices. This may in turn allow the
merged entity to raise price - Effect more likely to be significant when
proportion of foreclosed rivals is high or
foreclosed rivals are close competitors - Merger may allow merger entity to raise entry
barriers - In particular, if foreclosure establishes need
for two-level entry.
12Effects the SIEC test
- New test introduced to
- Consolidate an effects based approach in merger
assessment - Eliminate possible enforcement gaps
- Impact of the new test for non-horizontal
mergers - No need to establish dominance in the market
downstream - Need to establish likelyhood of significant
impact in effective competition (e.g. price
increase)
13Effects where?
- Competition policy protects competition, not
competitors. Consumer welfare standard is well
established. - Problem in vertical mergers some firms are both
customers and competitors to the merged entity - Principle Commission will focus on the effect on
customers immediately below the merged entity
(par 16)
14 - Example Siemens/ VA Tech (M.3653)
VA Tech (ETR) Electrical traction
Siemens Electrical traction
Siemens Rail vehicles
CAF
Even if the non-integrated suppliers of rail
vehicles, including the main non-integrated
supplier CAF, were eliminated from the market for
electrical rail vehicles, there would continue to
be in the individual Member States a sufficiently
large number of actual and potential competitors
in the overall train market.
15Effects efficiencies
- Efficiencies can counteract adverse effects on
competition - General principles apply
- to be identified by the merging parties
- be verifiable / be merger-specific/ benefit
consumers - Specific efficiencies to vertical mergers
- Internalisation of double mark-ups
- Reduction of inventories costs (e.g.
co-ordination of production and distribution) - Alignment of incentives (e.g. increased
investment in distribution)
16Conglomerate mergers
- Theories of harm
- Focus on anti-competitive foreclosure, through
tying and bundling - common practices, that often have no
anticompetitive consequences - in some circumstances they may deter entry or
harm consumers by reducing the rivals ability or
incentives to compete - No stand-alone  portfolio effects theory of
harm - Â the fact that the merged entity will have a
broad range of products does not, as such, raise
competition concerns - Three-step analytical framework
- ability / incentives / effects
- including assessment of efficiencies e.g. Cournot
effects economies of scope.
17Next steps
- Public consultation on draft ended on 12 May
2007. - 32 comments received. They are available at
- http//ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/legis
lation/non_horizontal_consultation.html - Commissions adoption of definitive version
expected by November 2007
18The new remedies policy
19Reasons and objectives of review
- Reflect conclusions from Commissions Merger
Remedies Study (2005) - http//ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/studi
es_reports/remedies_study.pdf - Incorporate recent jurisprudence
- Important guidance in EDP/GDP, GE, Tetra,
Cementbouw and easyjet judgements - Reflect experience gained in recent Commission
practice - Relevant recent remedies cases such as
Inco/Falconbridge or GDF/Suez - Update with regard to changes introduced in 2004
Merger Review - Mainly concerns options to extend deadlines to
discuss and assess remedies
20General Principles
- Allocation of responsibilities (EDP/GDP/ENI,
GE/Honeywell) - Commission informs the parties of the competition
concerns identified - It is for the parties to propose remedies,
Commission cannot unilaterally impose conditions
- Commission has to assess the effects of the
operation, as modified by the remedies - Commission has eventually to prove that remedies
are not sufficient to remove competition concerns - Proportionality (Cementbouw)
- Parties do not need to submit remedies that go
further than what is necessary to remove
competition concerns - If they do so, however, Commission cannot reject
them and impose different ones
21General Principles
- Assessment standard (GE/Honeywell, easyjet)
- Commitments have to eliminate competition
concerns entirely and to be comprehensive and
effective from all points of view - Certainty as to the implementation
- Probability as to the assessment of the operation
(more likely than not that the operation
modified significantly impedes effective
competition) - Appropriateness of different types of remedies
- Divestitures generally preferred, including for
non-horizontal concerns - Other structural commitments, such as access
remedies, acceptable if same effect as
divestiture divestitures as benchmark - Where market structure is affected only by future
behaviour of the merging parties, also other
remedies may have to be assessed (Tetra) - Commitments on future behaviour, however, only
exceptionally accepted. Certainty of
implementation and effective monitoring
particularly required (easyjet)
22Conclusions of the Remedy Study on divestitures
23Divestitures. Scope
- Insufficient scope of the divested business is
the major source of remedy failure (remedies
study).
24Divestitures. Scope
- All assets and personnel necessary to ensure
viable and competitive business to be transferred - Independent access to supply (Inco/Falconbridge
GDF/Suez Evraz/Highveld), IP rights, - Shared assets (duplication, if necessary) and
personnel to be transferred - Modalities
- Preference for stand-alone business
- Carve-outs acceptable
- Risks for viability and competitiveness to be
limited by requiring transfer of a stand-alone
business carve out started in interim period - Reverse carve out as option
- Divestiture of individual assets, brands,
licenses, re-branding - Acceptable in exceptional circumstances
- If resulting business will be immediately viable
in hands of suitable purchaser - In case of doubts concerning purchaser or
licensee, fix-it-first or up-front solution
preferable - Alternative divestitures (Crown jewels)
- In case of uncertainties for business to be
divested, parties can propose alternative
divestiture, to be implemented if the first one
does not take place in a short deadline.
25Divestitures. Additional information requirement
- There is a clear asymmetry of information on the
right scope of viable business Commission has
the burden of motivation to reject commitments - New information obligation of the parties in the
Implementing Regulation Form RM - Nature and scope of commitments offered
- Conditions for their implementation and
- Suitability to remove any impediment to effective
competition - Deviations from Commissions Model Texts
- For divestitures, in particular, detailed factual
description required on how the business is
currently operated to be compared with scope of
Divested Business as offered in the commitments
26Divestiture. Purchasers
- Divestiture only effective once business is
transferred to suitable purchaser - Suitable purchaser to be agreed within fixed
time-limit - Normal procedure.
- Multitude of purchasers available (also including
special purchaser requirements) - No specific issues interfere with divestiture
- Up-front buyer
- Uncertainty of implementation
- Obstacles for divestiture, e.g. third party
rights - Uncertainty that Business will attract suitable
purchaser - Difficult interim preservation
- If high risk of degradation
- Fix-it-first remedy
- Preferable where identity of purchaser is crucial
for effectiveness of remedy - E.g. if viability is ensured by specific assets
of the purchaser (Inco/Falconbridge) or where
purchaser needs to have specific characteristics
(tele.ring)
27Divestiture process
- Short divestiture two-step process (normally 63
months) - Interim preservation and hold separate
obligations - Monitoring Trustee
- Timely appointment as up-front trustee
- Trustee explicitly responsible for third party
complaints - Publication of identity and tasks
- Hold-separate manager
- Clear definition of role in commitments
- Immediate, up-front appointment
- Supervision/removal by Trustee
28Non divestiture remedies
- Removal of links with competitors
- Divestiture of minority shareholding or,
exceptionally, waiving rights related to minority
stakes - Termination of distribution or other contractual
arrangements - Access commitments
- Granting of non-discriminatory access to
infrastructure, networks, technology/IP rights or
essential inputs. - Acceptable, to lower barriers to entry or
eliminate foreclosure concerns, if same effect
as divestiture - For lowering entry barriers
- Ex. pay-TV platforms airport slots gas release
programs - Likely entry of new competitors
- For foreclosure concerns
- Access to pipelines, telecom networks, telematics
networks - Likely use by competitors
- For foreclosure concerns by IP rights or key
technology - Granting of non-exclusive licenses
- Ex. GE/Instrumentarium Axalto/Gemplus
- Monitoring of such commitments
- Self-enforcement of commitments via market
participants - Via arbitration clauses (ARD, easyjet)
- By national regulators
29Non divestiture remedies
- Other non-divestitures
- To be assessed on a case-by-case basis (Tetra)
- May be accepted in specific circumstances, such
as conglomerate concerns - Difficulty of monitoring and risks of
effectiveness they may only amount to mere
declarations of intentions
30Procedure Phase I remedies
- Remedies have to rule out serious doubts.
- Only acceptable when competition problem is
readily identifiable and can easily be remedied
(recital 30 ECMR). - To be submitted within 20 WD (extension 10 WD)
- Only limited modifications acceptable after
deadline (Philips) - Commission will offer opportunity to withdraw
remedies if concerns finally not arise in one or
more markets
31Procedure Phase II remedies
- Remedies must remove competition concerns
- They should be submitted before day 65
- If submitted before day 55, no extension
- If submitted after day 55 or before day 55 but
modified version submitted after, extension of 15
WD. - Art 10.3 extension possible
- Late modified remedies in phase-II
- Commission not obliged, but allowed to accept
late remedies (i.e. modified remedies submitted
after day 65). (Edp/GDP/Eni) - Conditions described in Remedies Notice
- Modified remedies fully and unambiguously remove
competition concerns without need for further
investigation or market test - Commission must be able to properly consult with
Member States, (i.e. to keep 10 WD deadline) - No Art 10.3 extension will normally be granted
after day 65
32Next steps
- Public consultation on draft ended on 29 June
2007 - 23 Comments received. They are available at
- http//ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/legi
slation/merger_remedies.html - Commissions adoption of definitive version
expected by early 2008.
33 - The Consolidated Jurisdictional Notice
34Scope and Sources
- Consolidation of current jurisdictional Notices
- Concept of Concentration
- Joint Ventures
- Undertakings concerned
- Calculation of Turnover
- Covers all issues relevant for Commissions
original jurisdiction under Merger Regulation - Sources for review
- New Merger Regulation
- Recent jurisprudence, i.e. Cementbouw and Endesa
- Decisional practice of Commission
- Adopted on 10 July 2007
35Concentration
- Acquisition of control by investment funds
- Normally
- Investment company acquires indirect control
under Article 3 (1), (3) - Investment company indirectly holds rights in
portfolio companies under Article 5(4) - Consequence turnover of all portfolio companies
is taken together, even if held by different
funds organised by same investment company
36Concentration
- Object of control
- Assets constituting a business with market
presence - Outsourcing cases Concentration only if
- Transfer of assets and/or personnel
- That allow acquirer to develop market presence
beyond outsourcing client - Time-frame similar to start-up period for
full-functionality of JVs
37Concentration
- (Joint) acquisition and immediate split-up of
target - Separate concentrations if
- Legally binding agreement on break-up
- No uncertainties that second transaction takes
place within short time-frame - Maximum normally 1 year
38Concentration
- Parking/warehousing transactions
- Interim purchaser acquires target on behalf of
ultimate purchaser on basis of agreement on
future on-sale - Often major part of economic risk shifted to
ultimate purchaser who may be granted specific
rights - First transaction considered first step in single
concentration comprising lasting acquisition of
of (parked) target by ultimate purchaser - First transaction no concentration in its own
right and not considered to fall under Article
3(5)
39Concentration
- Interrelated transactions when are several
transactions considered one concentration? - Under Article 3 Cementbouw, recital 20
- Transactions unitary in nature
- Transactions de jure or de facto interconditional
- Only if control is acquired by same
undertaking(s), not in cases of assets swaps or
de-mergers of JVs - Examples
- One business, one economic entity
- Parallel (EQT/HR/Dragoco) or serial acquisition
(Kingfisher) - Under Article 5(2)(2)
- Successive transactions between same parties
within two-year period considered one
concentration for calculation of turnover - Assessment under Article 3 is precedent
40Types of control
- Sole control comprises
- Positive sole control
- Negative control by minority shareholder
- De facto sole control on basis of past voting
pattern and prospective analysis - Joint control more on commonality of interests
and de facto situations - Reduction in number of shareholders
concentration only if change from joint to sole
control
41Joint Ventures
- Distinction between
- Joint acquisition of control of existing
undertaking, falling under Article 3(1) - Creation of a JV, falling under Article 3(4)
- Clarification of full-functionality criteria
42Community Dimension
- Relevant date for establishing jurisdiction
Earlier of - Date of notification to Commission or national
competition authorities - Conclusion of agreement, announcement of public
bid, etc. - Turnover calculation
- Normally based on audited accounts of previous
financial year - Adjustments to be made in case of permanent
changes in economic reality of undertakings
concerned (CFI in Endesa)