Title: Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
1Chapter 7General Equilibrium and Market
Efficiency
2Outline.
- A simple exchange economy
- Efficiency in production
- Efficiency in product mix
- Sources of inefficiency
3A simple exchange economy
- Consider a simple economy in which there are only
two consumers A (Ann) and B (Bill) and two goods
food and clothing. - Available quantities of goods are exogenous
- Food 100
- Clothing 200
- An allocation is an assignment of these
quantities between A and B. - The amounts of goods with which A and B start
each period are called their initial endowments.
4Personal bargaining
- What do A and B do with their initial endowments?
- They may either consume what they already have or
to engage in exchange one with the other. - Exchange is purely voluntary so it only takes
place if it is beneficial to both parties - Exchange makes someone better off if it places
him on a higher indifference curve
5The Edgeworth Box
6Improving utility through exchange
7Further improving utility through exchange
8Reaching a Pareto-optimal allocation
9The Contract Curve
10From initial endowments to the contract curve
11Market economies
- In our very simple example, exchange took place
through personal bargaining. In market economies,
most exchanges have a more impersonal character. - People have given endowments and they face given
prices. They then decide how many goods and
services they want to buy and sell. - We can introduce market-type exchanges by
assuming that there exists a third (fictive)
person playing the role of an auctioneer.
12Exchanges in a market economy
13General equilibrium in a market economy
14The first theorem of welfare economics
- It is also called the theorem of the Invisible
Hand. - It can be stated as follows an equilibrium
produced by competitive markets will exhaust all
possible gains from exchange. - Another way to put it is that equilibrium in
competitive markets is Pareto optimal
competitive equilibrium is efficient
15The second theorem of welfare economics
- It states that any allocation on the contract
curve can be sustained as a competitive
equilibrium. - The basic condition that assures this result is
that consumer indifference curves be convex when
viewed from the origin. - Why not redistribute initial endowments in order
to achieve the desired outcome directly? - Lack of information on consumers' indifference
curves - Consequence of the theorem the issue of equity
in distribution is logically separable from the
issue of efficiency in allocation
16Decentralisation of the optimum
17Outline.
- Efficiency in production
- Efficiency in product mix
- Sources of inefficiency
18Efficiency in production
- The product mix in an economy is the result of
the allocation of productive inputs - Suppose we add a productive sector to our
exchange economy. - It consists of 2 firms, each of them using
capital K and labour L. - Firm C produces clothing and firm F produces
food. - Suppose the total quantities of the 2 inputs are
fixed with K 50 and L 100. - The production processes used by the 2 firms
give rise to conventional convex-shaped
isoquants.
19The Edgeworth production box
20The efficiency of general equilibrium
- If firms maximise their profits, the resulting
general equilibrium will satisfy the requirements
of efficiency in production - Suppose that food and clothing prices are PF and
PC. - Suppose that firms hire labour and capital on
perfectly competitive markets at hourly rates w
and r. - If both firms minimise costs we have
- Given that the price of inputs is the same for
both firms, this yields
21Outline.
- Efficiency in product mix
- Sources of inefficiency
22Efficiency in production mix
- An economy may be efficient in production and, at
the same time do a very poor job in satisfying
the wants of its members - So, there is one more efficiency criterion of
concern which is whether the economy has an
efficient mix of the two products - To define the efficient product mix, it is
useful to translate the contract curve from the
Edgeworth production box into a production
possibilities frontier - Definition this is the set of all possible
output combinations that can be produced with
given quantities of capital and labour.
23(No Transcript)
24The marginal rate of transformation
- The slope of the production possibilities
frontier at any point is called the marginal rate
of transformation (MRT) - It measures the opportunity cost of clothing in
terms of food. - For the economy we consider, the MRT increases
when we move to the right. This is always the
case as long as there are constant or decreasing
returns to scale.
25Efficiency in product mix
- In order for an economy to be efficient in terms
of production mix, the MRS for each consumer has
to be equal to the MRT
26General equilibrium and efficiency in product mix
- Let PF and PC denote the equilibrium prices for
food and clothing. - As we have seen for the simple exchange economy,
in equilibrium, the MRS of every consumer will be
equal to the ratio of these prices PC / PF. - In order to show that the general equilibrium is
efficient, we need to show that the MRT is also
equal to PC / PF
27Demonstration
- Lets show that at any point on the production
possibilities frontier he MRT is equal to the
ratio of the marginal cost of clothing (MCC) to
the marginal cost of food (MCF). - The MRT is given by
-
- It is the amount of food you have to give up in
order to get one more unit of clothing. - In order to produce one more unit of clothing, we
need to use a bundle of inputs the value of which
is MCC.
28Demonstration (ctd1)
- In order to get that bundle of input, we need to
produce less food. - For each unit of food we give up, we get an input
bundle which is worth MCF. - So, in order to get an input bundle worth 1, we
need to give up 1/ MCF units of food - In order to get an input bundle worth MCC, we
need to give up MCC / MCF units of food. - So,
-
29Demonstration (ctd2)
- The equilibrium condition for food and clothing
producers is that product prices be equal to the
corresponding marginal costs. - PF MCF and PC MCC
- So,
- So, an economy in competitive general equilibrium
is simultaneously efficient (i.e. Pareto optimal)
in consumption, production and in the choice of
product mix. -
30Outline.
31Taxes in general equilibrium
32Taxes and inefficiency in the product mix
- Even with the tax on food, consumers have a
common value of MRS in equilibrium and that
producers have a common value of MRTS. So, the
economy is efficient in consumption and
production. - The tax causes producers to see a different price
ratio from the one seen by consumers consumption
decisions are based on gross prices whereas
production decisions are guided by net prices. - So, the MRS and MRT can never be equal in
equilibrium. - So, the tax leads to an inefficient production
mix.
33Minimising Distorsions
- Subsidies, like taxes upset the conditions
required for efficiency - The tax system has to be designed in order to
minimise distorsions - Taxing food and clothing at the same rate t.
- But in general, comodity taxes will have
distortionary effects - Lump-sum taxes
- But generate equity problems
- The best tax tax levied on activities of which
there would otherwise be too much
34Externalities
- Another source of inefficiency occurs when
production or consumption activities involve
benefits or costs for people not directly
involved in them. Such benefits and costs are
called externalities - Example of negative externality pollution
- Example of positive externality flowers
- Externalities create a problem very similar to
taxes they cause producers and consumers to
react to a different set of relative prices .
35Externalities (ctd)
- Solution
- Tax negative externalities
- Subsidise positive externalities
- The existence of externalities is a good example
of market failure - It is a case in which the outcome generated by
the working of the market is no optimal. - This sets the ground for public intervention in
the economy.
36Public goods
- Pure public goods have 2 characteristics
- They are non-rival the fact that one person uses
the good does not reduce the amount of good that
can be used by another person. - Example radio or TV programs, national defence.
- They are non-excludable it is impossible to
exclude somebody who does not pay from using the
good. - Example TV programs before cable TV, radio
programs, national defence - There is no reason to presume that private
markets will supply optimal quantities of pure
public goods
37Public goods (ctd)
- The problem is less acute with goods that are
non-rival but excludable. - Example cable TV. It is possible to exclude
people from watching programs they do not pay
for. - But even here there are likely to be
inefficiencies Once a TV program has been
produced, it costs society nothing to let an
extra person see it. - Here again, these market failures set the ground
for public intervention in the economy.