Title: Renewable Energy Production Payments
1Renewable Energy Production Payments
Renewable Energy Working Group Bend, March 22,
2006
Carel DeWinkel Renewable Energy
Division carel.dewinkel_at_state.or.us
2Outline of presentation
- Renewable Energy Production Payments (REPPs)
- Community-based energy development (C-BED)
- A Cost scenario for REPPs to meet part of the
REAP goal
3Renewable Energy Production Payments
- Often referred to as the European Feed-in
law - Prices set by a political process
- The amount of installed capacity determined by
market forces - This is the reverse of the RPS process
- Worldwide to date, this is the most consistent
and successful policy tool to promote renewables
4(No Transcript)
5(No Transcript)
6Renewable Energy Production Payments
- Excellent tool for the development of local
manufacturing capacity for example, countries
with the strongest domestic wind manufacturing
industry all had some kind of feed-in law
7Renewable Energy Production Payments
- Production based payments in the State of
Washington for PV, wind and digesters - In Minnesota 1.5 cents/kWh for small,
locally-owned wind farms and now the
Community-Based Energy Development Tariff
8REPPs Critical characteristics
- Tariff must be sufficiently high to drive
development - Private investors need fair and sufficient
profitability - Local banks often play an important role and see
these investments as relatively low risk - Long term contracts with minimum prices
- (often with an initial period of higher prices,
followed by a period of lower prices after the
loan has been paid off) - Rate based, like public purpose charge, no state
aid
9Critical characteristics, contd
- Prices are
- Adjusted by technology
- Adjusted by location (sites with the best
resource gets the lowest payment to avoid
windfall profits) - Adjusted by plant size
- Declining annually for new projects that come on
line - Flexible to adjust to technological changes
- Adjusted every two years by an independent
entity to adjust market penetration to reach the
desired goals
10Critical characteristics, contd
- Right to interconnect (like our PURPA)
- Elimination of barriers to interconnect
- Uniform standards for interconnection
- Easy permitting and siting
- High level of transparency
11Renewable Energy Production Payments
- This policy tool
- Promotes the development of distributed
renewable resources by smaller companies, coops
and individual citizens - Builds a strong constituency in favor of
renewables (compare wind in the UK with lots of
NIMBY problems versus Germany) - Can be used to promote renewables in
geographical areas where the resource is lower
than the most optimum sites - Can support a diversified portfolio of renewable
energy technologies
12Renewable Energy Production Payments Why?
- An RPS will not necessarily result in more
community-based renewable energy development
projects - Some RPS designs could actually make
community-based renewable energy development
impossible - utilities tend to use periodic RFPs to meet RPS
goals - only large-scale projects qualify for most RFPs
(some have minimum capacity requirements that
are larger than typical community-based
projects) - large scale wind has lower costs to rate payers
- But, who cares about community-based energy
development and what is it anyway?
13Community-based energy development (C-BED)
- Definition
- A community-based or locally-owned energy
project is generally defined as an energy project
in which one or more members of the local
community have a significant direct financial
stake in the project, other than through land
lease payments, tax revenue, or other payments in
lieu of taxes. The size of the projects is small
in comparison to typical large generating
projects owned by utilities or large commercial
developers (for example, large wind farms). But
they are bigger than the typical net-metering
type installations for homes and businesses.
14Community-based energy development (C-BED)
- Benefits
- Increased economic benefits to rural Oregon
(see recent OSU study for Umatilla county) - Community-based projects might get more local
buy-in for renewables and foster a climate for
more renewable development (fewer NIMBYs) - Distributed generation can be interconnected to
smaller transmission lines, thereby possibly
avoiding the need for additional power lines or
help avoid transmission problems - Smaller, multiple generating sites may help
stabilize the grid. - Spreading production facilities helps offset
variability in resources such as wind and solar,
plus it provides an increased level of energy
security - Small-scale projects may help develop bigger
projects in the future
15Community-based energy development (C-BED)
-
- But doesnt it cost more?
- In comparison to what?
- One answer is, yes, from a simple rate payers
perspective, a large wind farm is cheaper than,
for example, a community-based small wind farm. - BUT, a C-BED project may very well be cheaper
than its fossil fuel alternatives..Lets look
at some numbers
16Renewables Value of fuel savings and carbon
reductions only
- Fuel cost savings only, for a gas fired power
plant with a heat rate of 7,000 Btu per kWh - /BBL Oil /MMBtu Nat. Gas /MWh
- 60.00 10 70
- Carbon dioxide reduction, assuming a gas fired
power plant - 800 lbs/MWh, valued at 20/ton equals 8/
MWh - Total value of fuel savings and carbon reduction
is 78/MWh or 7.8 cents/kWh
17Numbers in the REAP context
- Assume that
- we agree that the value of fuel savings plus the
carbon reduction is 78/MWh or 7.8 cents/kWh
(from the previous page) - the REPP policy will only be used for projects of
10 MW or less, to fit the OPUC decision in UM
1129 (standard contracts, etc.) - UM1129 proceeding results in a PURPA tariff of
5.8 cents/kWh, but in constant real terms over
the contract period - the COUs as a group have the same avoided cost as
the IOUs - Then, from a societal point of view, we have 2
cents/kWh available for a production payment to
equal societys avoided cost of the fossil fuel
alternative...
18Numbers in the REAP context, the year 2015
- 10 renewables equals 571 aMW (IOUs408 aMW,
COUs163 aMW) - Assume that the average REPP would be 2 cents/kWh
and that the market of C-BED projects would grow
to about 20 of the REAP goal, or about 115 aMW
by the year 2015 - Assume that the REPP would be paid for by a
Public Purpose Charge - This would mean a ramp-up to the following costs
by 2015 - an annual cost for the IOUs of about 14 million
and for the COUs about 5.7 million - Or an extra cost of about 0.04 cents/kWh to the
rate payer - Or a rate increase of about 0.6 (current average
rate about 7 cents/kWh) - Or an extra annual cost of 4 for a rate payer
using 10,000 kWh/yr
19Numbers in the REAP context, the year 2015
- Note that the numbers shown in the previous slide
assume that the same incentive level is needed
for the whole period to 2015 - In reality, the avoided cost for the utilities
will most likely go up - Thus, unless the cost of the renewables increases
more rapidly than the utilities avoided cost,
the required REPP level to make new projects a
reality will decrease - It is possible that there wont be a need for a
REPP for new projects by the year 2015
20And finally
- The primary incentive tools currently available
in Oregon are all focussed on the smaller scale
projects - BETC with its 10 million limit per eligible
project cost - SELP with its 20 million limit on project cost
- The ETOs renewable budget of about 10 million
per year - The USDA Farm Bill with its grants, loans and
loan guarantees - To integrate Renewable Energy Production Payments
for projects of 10 MW or less with these existing
programs appears not to be overly difficult.
21Information Workshop
Renewable Energy Production Payments for small
to medium sized projects Salem, April 5, 2006
For more information, contact
carel.dewinkel_at_state.or.us