Title: Inflation in Bulgaria: Convergence or EUphoria
1Inflation in BulgariaConvergence or EU-phoria?
- Jianping Zhou1/
- International Monetary Fund
- May 2, 2007
- 1/ The views presented here are those of the
author and are not to be interpreted as those of
the IMF. Please do not quote without authors
permission.
2Background/Motivation
- Bulgarias joining the euro zone now hinges on
its ability to reduce its inflation differential
vis-à-vis the euro zone. - Remarkable progress was made over the last 10
years in bringing down the hyperinflation to a
single-digit rate today. - However, inflation has risen in recent years and
inflation gap widened, to 5 percentage points in
2006, although partly due one-off adjustments. - Large inflation gaps exist also in many other new
EU member states (NMS).
3Background/Motivation
4Background/Motivation
- The government is committed to early adoption of
the euro and confident in reducing inflation. - There is increasing skepticism that the NMS will
be able to fulfill the inflation criterion by
their targeted dates for joining the euro (about
three years from now for most of them) and
whether they even should (Kopits, 2006). - Price convergence closer integration with Europe
significantly increased trade and capital flows,
weakened border effects and reduced price
dispersions (Rogers, 2007). - Income convergence productivity catch-up
- The Balassa-Samuelson effect faster catch-up in
tradables sector relative to nontradables sector
5Background/Motivation
- The role of domestic policies may be limited
(Mody and Ohnsorge, 2006) a transitional
recession might be necessary to depress inflation
(Buiter and Grafe, 2002). - The persistence of inflation differentials across
the euro area countries since the introduction of
the euro also lends support to those opposing the
inflation criterion.
6(No Transcript)
7Background/Motivation
- High inflation, even transitory, should be a
matter of concern - when feeding into wage decisions, it may amplify
cyclical fluctuations - when a country with higher inflation is also
faced with lower real interest rates, it could
lead to excessive household debt accumulation,
over investment, and asset bubbles - Large and continually rising current account
deficits in Bulgaria and many other NMS raise
questions about whether higher inflation might
partly reflect EU-phoria expectations of rapid
income convergence and higher income propelled by
prospects of euro entry.
8Countries with high inflation tend to have larger
current account deficits.
9A summary
- Stylized facts about inflation in Bulgaria
- A theoretical model
- Examines the impacts of the B-S and the EIC
effects on inflation, consumption, output, and
the current account balance - Provides basis for the empirical framework
- Empirical investigations
- Partial correlations and panel regressions
- Preliminary results
10Inflation gap was closed in 2003 (and inflation
criteria met), but has widened since then
11The impact of administrative price adjustments
- In 2006 21 percent of the prices under the
government control a large increase in excise
duties for tobacco. - This share is higher than in 2000 (17 percent).
- Increases in these prices added about 1
percentage point to the average inflation rate. - it is not clear whether inflation would be lower
without these price controls. - Inflation excluding these prices has been highly
correlated with the overall inflation.
12Higher inflation in the nontradables sector than
in the tradables sector.
13Why would prices of nontradable goods increase
faster?
- The Balassa-Samuelson effect
- Relatively higher productivity growth in the
tradables sector - Differences in market structures (e.g., the
degree of competition) - Mody and Ohnsorge, 2006
- Arratibel and others, 2002
- Expected faster income convergence
- Results from the theoretical model
14The representative consumer with perfect
foresight expectations maximize an intertemporal
utility function.
15The representative firm produces the trade and
non-traded goods with the following production
function
16The consumers budget constraints are
17Impact of current and expected changes in
productivity on current inflation
- First term captures the classical
Balasaa-Samuelson effect an increase in the
productivity in tradable sector relative to
non-tradable sector raises the domestic price
level b/c it increases the consumption of the
tradable good relative to the non-tradable good. - Second and third terms capture the impact of
expected productivity growth.
18Impact of the B-S effect and expected
productivity growth on inflation, consumption,
output, and the current account balance
19Main results from the model
- Both the B-S and the EIC (measured by expected
productivity growth) effects would result in
higher price increases in non-tradable sector,
thus leading to high inflation. - They would have different impact on the relative
output of the tradable and non-tradable goods. - If the Balassa-Samuelson effect is at work, we
should observe that the increase in domestic
demand for the tradable good is offset by an
increase in supply, so that the trade balance
does not change. - By contrast, with the expected income convergence
the increase in demand is not matched by an
equivalent increase in supply and leads to a
trade deficit. - The presence of large current account deficit is
an indication that the EIC might be partly
responsible for the rising inflation in recent
years.
20Empirical evidence of the B-S effect
- Many studies investigating the sizable
cross-country differences in inflation in the
euro area find little or no evidence of the BS
effect (Honohan and Lane, 2003 2007 Roger,
2007 Mody and Ohnsorge, 2006). - For the transition countries in Europe, the
estimated B-S effect on inflation ranges from
zero to 4 percentage points (Mihaljek and
Klau,2003). - Existing studies on Bulgaria tend to find small
or insignificant B-S effect on inflation(AEAP,
2006 and Nenovsky and Dimitrova, 2002). - Reasons price liberalization, rigidities in
product and labor markets.
21Empirical evidence of the B-S effect
- Prices of non-traded goods have been rising much
faster than the prices of the traded goods, but
not due to the BS effect. - Productivity has been rising faster in the
nontradables sector, contrary to the B-S
hypothesis. - Employment in the non-tradable sector grew much
more rapidly than in the tradable sector. -
22Higher productivity growth across most
subsectors financial, business, personal, and
real estate-related services, wholesale and
retail sectors
23Bulgaria is not alone ...
24Poor NMS tend to converge faster, but Bulgaria is
below the line
25Convergence speed Bulgaria (1), vs. Ireland
(2.5).
26Poorer NMS are associated with higher inflation,
but Bulgaria is above the line
27The convergence process has been accompanied by
accelerated capital inflows, adding inflationary
pressures
28Based on the correlation in Figure 14, Bulgarias
inflation should be about 4 percent
29Same holds for average inflation in 2004-06
30Its current account deficit should be about 10
percent of GDP (similar to what implied by
Blanchard Giavazzi, 2002)
31To the extent that CAB reflects expectations for
higher future income, economic agents in Bulgaria
appear to be becoming increasingly optimistic.
32Panel regressions
33Preliminary results
- We find no significant Balassa-Samuelson effect
on inflation in Bulgaria. - It is possible that EU-phoria or expected rapid
income convergence is partly responsible for the
relatively higher inflation in Bulgaria. - Is inflation in Bulgaria too high?
- Past performances
- Standards set by certain countries (e.g.,
Ireland) - Supply side polices needed to ensure rapid income
convergence
34Concluding remarks
- The large current account deficit, buoyant credit
growth, and inflationary pressures all point to a
certain degree of EU-phoria expectations of
faster convergence and higher future income. - The presence of the risks associated with
unrealized expectations, either because of
unexpected adverse external shocks or because of
unsuccessful domestic policies to deliver
expected high productivity growth, underlines the
need for policy safeguards. - With the currency board arrangement in place,
tight fiscal policy remains the key instrument in
containing domestic demand and reducing
overheating. - Other important measures would include prudent
wage policies, strengthened financial regulation
and supervisions, and last but most importantly,
structural reforms to improve the flexibility of
the economy.
35Some caveats
- Empirical results are based on work in progress,
and should be interpreted with cautions. - CAB may be capturing other effects, e.g., trade
and financial integration - Data issues
- Policy discussions emphasize on the risks
associated with volatile expectations, not on
whether these expectation are exuberant - Future work to better capture the degree of
EU-phoria - Stochastic expectations
- Engel and Rogers (2006) the expected future US
growth is measured by its expected future share
of world GDP to its current share of world GDP