Incentive Regulation for Recurrent Expenditure: Benchmarking and CarryOvers - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 22
About This Presentation
Title:

Incentive Regulation for Recurrent Expenditure: Benchmarking and CarryOvers

Description:

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. 2 April 2004. 2. What is the issue? ... decisions for TNSPs - either for opex alone or for both opex and capex? ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:33
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 23
Provided by: DBi7
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Incentive Regulation for Recurrent Expenditure: Benchmarking and CarryOvers


1
Incentive Regulation for Recurrent
ExpenditureBenchmarking and Carry-Overs
  • Darryl Biggar
  • Consulting Economist
  • Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
  • 2 April 2004

2
What is the issue?
  • In updating the Statement of Regulatory
    Principles two questions naturally arise
  • Should the ACCC make more use of external
    benchmarking in setting the expenditure targets?
  • Should the ACCC make use of an efficiency
    carry-over mechanism?
  • in its revenue cap decisions for TNSPs - either
    for opex alone or for both opex and capex?

3
Incentive regulation
  • These issues relate to the design of incentive
    regulation for TNSPs
  • Incentive regulation is about giving the firm
    financial rewards for pursuing desirable
    objectives
  • such as promoting service quantity and quality
    or reducing expenditure (opex or capex)
  • Theory suggests that the power of the incentives
    to promote different objectives should be
    balanced
  • Incentives to maintain service quality should be
    balanced with incentive to reduce expenditure
  • Incentive to reduce opex may need to be balanced
    with incentive to reduce capex

4
Incentive regulation
  • The power of the incentive to reduce
    expenditure depends on the sensitivity of the
    firms profit stream to a change in its own
    expenditure
  • The revenue stream is fixed for the remainder of
    the regulatory period so the power of the
    incentive to reduce expenditure depends primarily
    on the sensitivity of the future revenue stream
    to expenditure out-turns in the current period.
  • In particular, in the case of recurrent
    expenditure, the power of the incentive to reduce
    expenditure depends primarily on how future
    revenue targets are set in the light of past
    expenditure out-turns

5
Incentive regulation
  • The power of the incentive to reduce recurrent
    expenditure depends on how information on past
    expenditure out-turns
  • is used in the setting of future revenue
    targets.

6
Need for a mechanistic approach
  • If a regulatory regime is to have known and
    predictable incentive properties the regulator
    must commit to a mechanistic approach to using
    past out-turn information when setting the future
    revenue targets.
  • To the extent that the scrutiny of external
    consultants acts as a control on the revenue
    targets the precise manner in which the
    consultants determine the appropriate level of
    cost is of primary importance for assessing the
    power of the incentive scheme Any attempt to
    clarify the process will inevitably involve ..
    Replacing this discretionary process with a more
    mechanistic process.
  • There must be some formula by which past
    expenditure out-turns are converted into future
    revenue targets

7
Carry-over Mechanism
  • Some regulators make use of a carry-over which
    sets the revenue target as the sum of an
    underlying target and a carry-over

Underlying target Year 6
Underlying target Year 7
Underlying target Year 8
Underlying target Year 9
Underlying target Year 10
Carry-over Year 6
Carry-over Year 7
Carry-over Year 8
Carry-over Year 9
Carry-over Year 10


8
Carry-over Mechanism
  • But the incentive properties depend only on how
    the total amount of revenue the firm receives
    depends on the past out-turns
  • In particular, it is not possible to determine
    the incentive properties of a regulatory regime
    by examining the carry-over alone
  • The incentive properties of a regulatory regime
    can only be understood if the regulator commits
    to a mechanistic process for setting both (a) the
    underlying targets and (b) the carry-over.
  • But why make things more complicated and less
    transparent?

9
Carry-over Mechanism
  • Several submissions said that the efficiency
    carry-over mechanism
  • is a tool for overcoming the information
    asymmetry that exists between the regulated firm
    and the regulator
  • causes the regulated firm to reveal the
    efficient costs of business to the regulator
  • But is this right?
  • Theory shows that no mechanism based on the
    firms own costs can induce the firm to reveal
    its fully efficient costs
  • But increasing the power of an incentive
    mechanism can increase the incentive to reduce
    expenditure

10
Properties of different mechanisms
  • If the regulator is going to commit to a
    mechanistic approach to setting the future
    revenue targets which approach should it choose?
  • How should the revenue targets depend on
    information on past expenditure out-turns?
  • Ideally we would like constant incentives for
    minimising expenditure over time
  • Incentives for minimising expenditure should be
    balanced with incentives to enhance service
    quantity and quality.
  • Lets examine the effects of different approaches

11
Example 1
  • Suppose first that the regulator sets the future
    revenue targets on the basis of the expenditure
    out-turn in the last year of the last regulatory
    period
  • This creates very strong incentives to reduce
    costs in the first four years of the regulatory
    period and very strong incentives to increase
    costs in the last year

12
Example 2
  • Now suppose that we add an efficiency carry-over
    mechanism to this approach
  • Now we have constant incentives to reduce
    expenditure over time
  • But there are other approaches

13
Example 3
  • Now suppose that the revenue targets are set on
    the basis of a weighted average of the
    expenditure out-turn in the previous regulatory
    period
  • Again we have achieved constant incentives to
    reduce expenditure over time

14
Example 4
  • Now suppose that we add an efficiency carry over
    to example 3
  • Now we have mild incentives to raise costs in
    years 1-4 and very strong incentives to reduce
    costs in year 5

330
15
Interim conclusions
  • These examples re-emphasise the following points
  • The incentive properties of an incentive
    mechanism depend not just on the carry-over but
    on how both the carry-over and the underlying
    targets are set
  • The use of an efficiency carry-over may make a
    bad outcome better or a good outcome bad,
    depending on how the underlying targets are set
  • The use of an efficiency carry-over, when
    combined with setting the underlying targets on
    the basis of the last year of the last regulatory
    period is entirely equivalent to setting the
    underlying targets on the basis of a weighted
    average of all the previous out-turns

16
Interim conclusions
  • Conclusion A carry-over mechanism is not
    necessary and is potentially harmful or
    misleading
  • The simplest approach to achieve constant
    incentives is to set the revenue targets for the
    next regulatory period on the basis of a weighted
    average of the expenditure out-turns for the
    previous regulatory period.
  • But is it the case that a revenue target based on
    a weighted average will always yield sufficient
    revenue?
  • Recurrent expenditure could be higher due to
    exogenous factors such as
  • Changes in wage rates or exchange rates Changes
    in the size of the network Changes in the age of
    the network

17
Handling scope changes
  • These factors can be taken into account by adding
    or subtracting an exogenous amount from the
    simple weighted average
  • We can add or subtract an arbitrary amount
    without affecting the incentives as long as the
    amount added or subtracted is exogenous that
    is, completely independent of past expenditure
    out-turns
  • This exogenous offset can be used to take
    account of factors which shift expenditure (such
    as changes in wage rates or exchange rates)

18
Handling scope changes
  • In addition, as a further protection, the
    regulator could give the regulated firm the
    option of a recovering its actual expenditure ex
    post.
  • This approach ensures that the regulated firm is
    able to recover its actual costs, if actual costs
    are higher than expected
  • This is an example of the menu of options
    approach mentioned in the discussion paper
  • Analogously, both ESC and ESCOSA have chosen to
    not carry-over a negative carry-over amount
    which also increases the likelihood that the firm
    will be adequately compensated

19
Exogenous Cost Measures
  • We have discussed how the revenue targets should
    depend on the firms own expenditure out-turns
    but in theory it might be possible to cut the
    link with a firms own expenditure out-turns
    entirely by setting the revenue targets purely on
    exogenous cost measures (also sometimes called
    benchmarking)
  • For example, in theory we could use information
    on the performance of other TNSPs to develop an
    estimate of the efficient long-run cost of one
    TNSP
  • This would yield high-powered incentives for
    reducing expenditure (not necessarily desirable)
  • There would be no need for an efficiency
    carry-over

20
Exogenous Cost Measures
  • But there was little enthusiasm for pursuing this
    approach
  • Given the large number of factors which affect
    TNSP expenditure and the small number of
    comparator firms it would be difficult to create
    a suitable cost model.
  • Capex is highly variable over a long time period
    so benchmarking of capex was viewed as
    infeasible
  • Note the ACCCs current use of certain ratios as
    a sanity check is not benchmarking and is of
    limited use contains serious flaws and is
    totally unsuited to be used to imply a TNSP is
    efficient or to reward or penalise a TNSP for its
    performance. SPI PowerNet

21
The Way Forward
  • I propose the ACCC adopt a mechanistic approach
    to setting the revenue targets for recurrent
    expenditure
  • The underlying target for future periods would
    be set on the basis of the weighted average of
    the expenditure out-turns in previous periods
  • In addition, any exogenous differences in cost
    across periods which can be anticipated would be
    addressed through an exogenous offset (positive
    or negative) which is independent of past
    expenditure out-turns
  • Finally, the regulated firm would have the option
    ex post of obtaining recovery of actual
    expenditure (through an adjustment to the RAB).

22
The Way Forward
  • SPI PowerNet propose a similar approach
  • Opex expenditure during the future regulatory
    period would be set at the average of the
    preceding five years expenditure (adjusted for
    inflation) thus ensuring consumers receive the
    benefits of any efficiencies achieved .
  • This would be adjusted up or down for movements
    in uncontroversial, simple and clear exogenous
    costs such as OHS regulations and standards,
    environmental regulations, legislative changes,
    property taxes, insurance costs, etc.
  • Further adjustments would need to be made for
    volume effects as the assets under management can
    increase substantially during a five-year
    regulatory period .
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com