Title: Airport Charges
1Airport Charges their Potential for Abuse
- 3rd July 2007
- Presentation to the Expert Group on Air Transport
- IMPRINT-NET
- Ian Clayton
2Market Power
- Many EU airports enjoy high levels of market
power, as the supply of airport infrastructure is
finite potentially constrained - runway constraints are the most difficult to
overcome so - typically, availability of morning peak
departures slots becomes the constraining factor
- demand for airport infrastructure is increasing,
as competition in the airline market intensifies
- as a result, a number of larger EU airports have
been regulated.
3Airport Profitability
- The most profitable customers for airports are
short haul scheduled carriers because - flights operate all year round
- passengers are increasingly travelling for
business purposes - leisure passengers are less tied to traditional
summer breaks - EU integration has stimulated the VFR market
- flights operate relatively full
- airline pricing models ensure high load factors
- flights operate all day long
- efficient airline business models require optimal
fleet utilisation - simple route structure minimal complexity so
- an airports most profitable customers are the
same ones over which it may exercise the most
market power.
4Investment Return
- The directors of companies are obligated to seek
an optimal balance of risk return for their
shareholders so - to be an attractive investment, airports must
deliver a return over above that which the
stock market would typically deliver for a
similar level of risk - risks in the EU aviation sector have diminished,
as a result of market maturation so - airports have increasingly focused on delivering
increased returns however - where airports are regulated, this has led to
some interesting pricing structures
5Airport Revenues (1)
- Fundamentally, in order to deliver an attractive
return on investment, airports must increase
their revenues - where these revenues are subject to price
regulation, airport operators will seek to - find ways to realise revenues outside the scope
of regulation - find ways to realise increased regulated
revenues, where the regulatory system allows
this - outside the scope of regulation might mean
- through commercial activities
- through vertical integration
- through common interest
- regulatory systems may reward efficiency so
airports may over-forecast expenditure in order
to benefit from this.
6Airport Revenues (2)
Shareholders
Airport Operator
Aeronautical Charges
Property Rents, unregulated charges etc.
Property Rents, unregulated charges etc.
Retail, car parking, hotels etc.
Service Providers
Airlines
Fees
Passengers
Fares
7Increased Revenues through Commercial Activities
(1)
- A dual-till system allows unregulated revenues
from commercial activities, whereas aeronautical
activities are regulated so - OPEX allocated to the regulated, aeronautical
till are guaranteed to be remunerated through
airport charges - consequently, commercial activities can deliver
increased net revenues eg. - in 2005/6, Schiphol Group allocated 74 of OPEX
at Amsterdam (dual-till) to aeronautical
activities, recovering 10.72/passenger, whereas
BAA allocated just 24 of OPEX at Heathrow
(single-till) to aeronautical activities,
recovering 7.11/passenger so - returns on commercial activities at Amsterdam
were 130, whereas those at Heathrow were 61.
8Increased Revenues through Commercial Activities
(2)
- Airport retail is demonstrably not in competition
with other retail channels - retail commercial rents accrue to a single
landlord - passengers are required to dwell at airport
retail facilities - passengers are decreasing provided with catering
on short haul flights - heightened security requirements preclude some
products (eg. cosmetics) being carried through
control posts - there may be tax advantages to airport shopping
- the benefits of commercial revenues flow from
passengers, airlines, service providers others,
yet where a dual-till regulatory mechanism
exists, these accrue just to the airports sector.
9Increased Revenues through Vertical Integration
(1)
- Where airport operators own (or control) service
providers, there exists a potential to distort
competition eg. - although the EC Groundhandling Directive ensures
that charges for access to monopoly
infrastructure must be non-discriminatory
transparent, this does not effectively preclude
an airport operator from making excessive charges
to all groundhandlers, for access to its monopoly
infrastructure - from a group perspective this would
- be cost-neutral between an airport operator its
subsidiary but - deliver increased overall revenues, where
third-party groundhandlers operate - where accounts are consolidated, such abusive
behaviour is difficult to prove.
10Increased Revenues through Vertical Integration
(2)
11Increased Revenues through Vertical Integration
(3)
12Increased Revenues through Vertical Integration
(4)
13Increased Revenues through Common Interest (1)
- Where an airports shareholders share a common
interest with those of airlines, there exists a
potential to distort competition as - airport charges may be structured to deliver
advantage to a favoured airline eg. - by weighting charges away from a particular
business model or - by weighting charges towards or away from
passenger or aircraft activity - a rational investor would chose a charging regime
that was structured in such a way as to deliver
the maximum net present value of benefits from a
portfolio of assets - in a constrained airport, this is likely to be
one which incentivises best use of
infrastructure, such as high load factors quick
turnaround of aircraft, ie. is weighted towards
aircraft activity.
14Increased Revenues through Common Interest (2)
- the Schiphol Group is owned (76) controlled by
the Dutch state ( 24 owned by regional
Government) - AF/KLM is 21 owned by the previous shareholders
of KLM, who are predominantly Dutch investors - airport charges at Schiphol favoured transfer
passengers over point-to-point passengers, by a
factor of 31 (26.00 vs 8.67) - 60-70 of AF/KLMs passengers are transferring
through Amsterdam.
15Rewards for Efficiency
- Regulatory systems may allow airports to retain
so-called capital operational efficiencies
stemming from - capital savings
- operation savings
- increased commercial revenues however
- these are simply the differences between forecast
actual expenditure /or revenues - between 2003 2008, BAA under spent its capital
budget at Stansted by 229m (40) so is
currently achieving returns of 11.41, in
contrast to a regulatory settlement of 7.75 - the UK CAA is considering changing the regulatory
mechanism in order to return such revenues to
airlines.
16Key Points
- Constrained airports enjoy excessive market
power, potentially over their most profitable
customers - airport owners are obligated to seek to maximise
returns - this can be achieved through increasing revenues
outside the scope of regulation by leveraging
regulatory systems - dual-till, vertical integration common interest
all have the potential to distort competition - experience shows that the majority of abuse takes
place in constrained airports, whether or not
these are regulated so - rigorous targeted regulation is needed to
increase competition.