Title: Lecture 2 Auction Design
1Lecture 2Auction Design
This lecture derives bidding rules for some
auctions where there is incomplete information,
and discusses the the virtues and shortfalls of
alternative auction mechanisms. First we
explore the concept of revenue equivalence, which
is weaker than congruence, and applies to private
value auctions where the bidders are risk
neutral. Then we relax the conditions for
revenue equivalence to apply, seeking to show the
effects on bidding behavior and auction
revenue. Finally we discuss the role of
collusion and entry in auctions.
2Review of Lecture 1 Congruence revisited
Using the concept of congruence we derived two
rules for bidding Rule 1 Pick the same
reservation price in a Dutch auction that you
would submit in a first price sealed bid
auction. Rule 2 In private value auctions, or
if there are only two bidders, choose the
reservation price for an English or a Japanese
auction, that you would submit in a second price
sealed bid auction.
3Review of Lecture 1Second price auctions
- We also proved that the bidding strategy in
sealed bid second price auctions (and ascending
auctions) is very straightforward if you know
your own valuation. - Rule 3 In a second price sealed bid auction,
bid your valuation if you know it.
4Relaxing congruence
- In congruent auctions, the revenue to the
auctioneer and the payoffs to each bidder are
identical for every game history generated by a
solution strategy profile. - This is a very strong form of equivalence, and
often not met. The bidders and the auctioneer may
be indifferent between two auctions that are not
congruent to each other. - For example, suppose the auctioneer and the
bidders only care about their expected utility
from respectively conducting and participating in
an auction, and did not care about whether each
individual game history has the same outcome. - Can we show that such players might be
indifferent to certain non-congruent auctions
(where there is incomplete information)?
5Revenue Equivalence Defined
- The concept of revenue equivalence provides a
useful tool for exploring this question. - Two auction mechanisms are revenue equivalent if,
given a set of players their valuations, and
their information sets, the expected surplus to
each bidder and the expected revenue to the
auctioneer is the same. - Therefore revenue equivalence is a less stringent
condition than congruence. - Thus two congruent auctions are invariably
revenue equivalent, but not all revenue
equivalent auctions are congruent.
6Why study revenue equivalence ?
- If the auctioneer and the bidders are risk
neutral, studying revenue equivalence yields
conditions under which the players are
indifferent between auctions that are not
necessarily congruent. - Exploiting the principle of revenue equivalence
can sometimes give bidders a straightforward way
of deriving their solution bid strategies. -
7Preferences and Expected Payoffs
Let U(vn) denote the expected value of the nth
bidder with valuation vn bidding according to
his equilibrium strategy when everyone else does
too. P(vn) denote the probability the nth
bidder will win the auction when all players bid
according to their equilibrium strategy. C(vn)
denote the expected costs (including any fees to
enter the auction, and payments in the case of
submitting a winning bid).
8An Additivity Assumption
- We suppose preferences are additive, symmetric
and private, meaning - U(v) P(v) v - C(v)
- So the expected value of participating in the
auction is additive in the expected benefits of
winning the auction and the expected costs
incurred.
9A revealed preference argument
- Suppose the valuation of n is vn and the
valuation of j is vj. - The surplus from n bidding as if his valuation
is vj is U(vj), the value from participating if
his valuation is vj, plus the difference in how
he values the expected winnings compared to to a
bidder with valuation vj, or (vn vj)P(vj). - In equilibrium the value of n following his
solution strategy is at least as profitable as
deviating from it by pretending his valuation is
vj. Therefore - U(vn) gt U(vj) (vn vj)P(vj)
10Revealed preference continued
- For convenience, we rewrite the last slide on
the previous page as - U(vn) - U(vj) gt (vn vj)P(vj)
- Now viewing the problem from the jth bidders
perspective we see that by symmetry - U(vj) gt U(vn) (vj vn)P(vn)
- which can be expressed as
- (vn vj)P(vn) gt U(vn) - U(vj)
11A fundamental equality
- Say vn gt vj.which then implies P(vn)gt P(vj).
- Putting the two inequalities together, we
obtain - (vn vj) P(vn)gt U(vn) - U(vj) gt (vn vj) P(vj)
- Writing
- vn vj dv
- yields
- which, upon integration, yields
12Revenue equivalence
- This equality shows that in private value
auctions, the expected surplus to each bidder
does not depend on the auction mechanism itself
providing two conditions are satisfied - 1. In equilibrium the auction rules award the bid
to the bidder with highest valuation. - 2. The expected value to the lowest possible
valuation is the same (for example zero). - Note that if all the bidders obtain the same
expected surplus, the auctioneer must obtain the
same expected revenue.
13A theorem
- Assume each bidder
- - is a risk-neutral demander for the auctioned
object - - draws a signal independently from a common,
strictly increasing, cumulative continuous
distribution function. -
- Consider auction mechanisms where
- - the buyer with the highest signal always wins
- - the bidder with the lowest feasible signal
expects zero surplus. -
- Then the same expected revenue will be
generated by the auctions, and each bidder will
make the same expected payment as a function of
her signal.
14First price sealed bid private value action for
wireless licenses
15Second price sealed bid private value action for
wireless licenses
16All pay private value auction
17The Revenue from Private Value Auctions
Since any auction satisfying the conditions for
the theorem can be used to calculate the expected
revenue, we select the second price, or English
auction, to accomplish this task.
18Steps for deriving expected revenue
- The expected revenue from any auction satisfying
the conditions of the theorem, is the expected
value of the second highest bidder. - To obtain this quantity, we proceed in two
steps - 1. derive and analyze the probability
distribution of the highest valuation, - 2. and then derive the probability distribution
of the second highest bidder.
19The unconditional probability of winning
- From the perspective of the auctioneer, or an
outsider who does not know the valuation of any
player, each player has an equal chance of
winning the auction. - Given N bidders, each of whom has the same
chance of winning, the probability of bidder n
winning the auction is 1/N. - Each player knows his own valuation vn and
consequently has more information than the
auctioneer. - In the solution to a second price sealed bid
auction, each bidder submits her own valuation to
the auctioneer, and therefore the winning bidder
is the player with the highest valuation.
20The probability of winning an auction conditional
on your own valuation
- That is the probability of winning an auction in
equilibrium is just the probability of being
endowed with the highest valuation. - If valuations are identically and independently
distributed with cumulative probability
distribution function F(v), the probability that
v1, for example, is the highest of the N
valuations equals - Pr(v2 ? v1) ? (v3? v1) ?. . . ? (vN ? v1)
- Prv2 ? v1x Pr(v3? v1) x . . . x PrvN ? v1
- F (v1) x F (v1) x . . . x F (v1) (N-1
times) - F (v1)N-1
21The probability of the median valuation winning
an auction
- Conditioning on your own valuation, as N
increases the probability of winning the auction
declines at a much faster rate than 1/N does. - For example if v1 is the median of the
distribution, the probability of winning the
auction when N2 is 0.5. - But the probability of winning the auction when
N10 is - 0.59 1. 953110-3
- which is orders of magnitude less than 1/10.
22The probability of winning an auction with a
median valuation as a function of the number of
bidders
23Expected revenue in a private value auction
- The expected revenue to the auctioneer is the
expected value of the second highest valuation.
This can be calculated as -
- Hence the expected revenue for a private values
auction satisfying the conditions of the theorem
is this formula.
24Bidding Rules for Private Value Auctions
Armed with the formula on the previous slide, we
can also derive the solution bidding strategies
for auctions that are revenue equivalent to the
second price sealed bid auction.
25Bidding function in a first price sealed bid
auction
- Consider, for example a first price sealed bid
auctions with independent and identically
distributed valuations. - In a symmetric equilibrium to first price sealed
bid auction, we can show that a bidder with
valuation vn bids
26An example the uniform distribution
- Valuations are uniformly distributed within the
closed interval . In this case - which implies
27Bidding function with the uniform distribution
- Thus in the case of the uniform distribution the
equilibrium bid of the player with valuation v is
to bid a weighted average of the lowest possible
valuation and his own, where the weights are
respectively 1/N and (N-1)/N
28Comparison of bidding strategies
- The bidding strategies in the first and second
price auctions markedly differ. - In a second price auction bidders should submit
their valuation regardless of the number of
players bidding on the object. - In the first price auction bidders should shave
their valuations, by an amount depending on the
number of bidders.
29All pay sealed bid auction with private values
- The revenue equivalence theorem implies that the
amount bidders expect to pay in an all-pay
auction as in all other auctions satisfying the
conditions of the theorem. - In contrast to a first or second price sealed
bid auctions where only the winner bidder pays
his bid or the second highest bid in an all pay
auction losers also pays their bids. - The amount paid by the nth bidder is certain,
and not paid with the probability of winning the
auction, that is F(vn)N-1. - By the revenue equivalence theorem the amount
each bidder expect to pay in the first two
auctions, upon seeing their valuation, equals the
amount the bidder actually does pay in all pay
auction.
30Expected revenue in all pay auction
- In an all pay auction the expected revenue from
a bidder with vn bids F(vn)N-1 multiplied by the
amount he would bid in a first price auction. - This is
31When does Revenue Equivalence Fail?
- Bidders might be risk averse, not risk neutral.
- The private valuations of bidders might be drawn
from the probability distribution that are not
identical. - The theorem does not apply when bidders receive
signals about the value of the object to them
that are correlated with each other. - Collusion and entry deterrence are also
considerations that auctioneers should account
for.
32Attitudes towards risk in second price sealed bid
auctions with private values
- It remains a weakly dominant strategy for each
player to bid his or her valuation. - The optimal bidding strategy for the second
price sealed bid auction (and also the Japanese
and English auctions) is independent of a
bidder's attitude towards risk and uncertainty
when private values are drawn from a common
probability distribution.
33Attitudes towards risk in first price sealed bid
auctions with private values
- A strategy of bidding your valuation guarantees
exactly zero surplus. - If you place a lower bid than your valuation
your expected surplus initially increases until
it reaches the maximum for a risk neutral bidder,
and then falls, but the variance of the surplus
increases as well. - A risk averse gambler is willing to trade a
lower expected value to reduce the amount of
uncertainty, he accordingly bids higher than a
risk neutral bidder.
34Comparing first and second price sealed bid
auctions
- Revenue generated by a second price auction is
independent of the bidders' preferences over
uncertainty, since bidding is unaffected. - The revenue generated by the first price auction
is the same as the revenue generated by a second
price auction when bidders are risk neutral. - Therefore risk averse bidders generate more
revenue in a first price auction than they would
in a second price auction, and they generate more
revenue in a first price auction than do risk
neutral bidders.
35Asymmetric valuations
- In many auctions where there are private
valuations, the bidders have different uses for
the auctioned object, and this may be common
knowledge to all the bidders. - Bidder knows the probability distributions that
each of the other valuations are drawn from, he
will typically use that information when making
his own bid. - This affects the revenue equivalence theorem,
and also the auctioneer's preferences towards
different types of auctions.
36An example of asymmetry
- Instead of assuming that all bidders appear the
same to the seller and to each other, suppose
that bidders fall into two recognizably different
classes. - Instead of there being a single distribution
F(v) from which the bidders draw their
valuations, there are two cumulative
distributions, F1(v) and F2(v). - Bidders of type i?1,2 draw their valuations
independently from the distribution Fi(v). - Let fi(x) denote the probability density
function of Fi(x).
37Asymmetry in a first price auction with only two
bidders
- The private valuation of the first bidder is
drawn from a probability distribution F1(v) that
stochastically dominates the probability
distribution for the other probability
distribution F2(v). - In fact we make a stronger assumption, that for
all v - Then b1(v)lt b2(v). The intuition is to bid
aggressively from weakness and vice versa.
38Asymmetric first price sealed bid auction
39Base experiment for asymmetry with only one type
of players
40Incomplete information about the type of the
bidder
- Suppose each bidder sees his valuation, but does
not immediately learn whether he comes from the
high or low probability distribution. - At that point the bidding strategy cannot depend
on which probability distribution the valuation
comes from. - Then each bidder is told which probability
distribution his bid is drawn from. - How should he revise his bid? The second (first)
bidder learns that the first (second) bidder is
more likely to draw a higher (lower) valuation
than himself, realizes the probability of winning
falls (rises), so adjusts his upwards
(downwards).
41Auction Design
In this part of the lecture we relax the
independence assumption for revenue equivalence
to apply, discuss the winners curse, and show
the effects on bidding behavior and auction
revenue. Finally we discuss the role of collusion
and entry in auctions.
42Relaxing independence
- The revenue equivalence theorem applies to
situations in which the valuation of each is
bidder is independently distributed, and this is
is what we have been focusing on in the first
part of this lecture. - This is not always a useful assumption, because
in many situations a bidder would be informed if
he had information about the object on the
auction block that another bidder had, and would
use the information in a similar way. - What happens when the signals that bidders get
about the value of the auctioned item are
positively correlated?
43Symmetric Valuations
- What happens when the signals that bidders get
about the value of the auctioned item are
positively correlated? - We relax independence and consider the class of
symmetric valuations, which have two defining
features - 1. All bidders have the same utility function.
- 2. Each bidder only cares about the collection
of signals received by the other bidders, not
who received them. - Thus we may write the valuation of bidder n as
44An example Value of the object not known to
bidders
- Suppose the value of the object to each bidder
is the same, but this value is unknown to each
bidder. The nth bidder receives a signal sn which
is distributed about the common value v, and
write - sn v ?n where ?n ? EvInformation of n
v - where ?n is independently distributed.
- More generally, each bidder might place more
significance on their own draw, but still attach
some value to the assessments of others.
45Summary so far
- When comparing two (or more) auctions, we should
consider the following questions - Are the auctions congruent, or if not, revenue
equivalent? - Are the bidders risk neutral?
- In private valuation auctions, are bidders
drawing from the same probability distribution? - In common valuation auctions, are bidders drawing
from the same distribution of signals?
46English auction with common value
47Dutch auction with common value
48The winner's curse
- When other bidders have information that you
lack about the value of the object for sale,
winning the auction may cause you to decrease
your conditionally expected value of the object. - Failure to take into account the bad news about
others' signals that comes with any victory is
called the winner's curse. - The winner's curse describes the fact that
winning an auction may convey new and unfavorable
information about the item. - Because all other bids are less than the winning
bid, the expected value of the item to the
winning bidder might fall when the outcome of the
auction is announced.
49The expected value of the item upon winning the
auction
- If the nth bidder wins the auction, he will
realize his signal exceeded the signals of
everybody else, that is - sn maxs1,,sN
- so he will condition the expected value of the
item on this new information. - His expected value is now the expected value of
vn conditional upon observing the maximum signal - Evn sn maxs1,,sN
- This is the value that the bidder should use in
the auction, not Evnsn, because he should
recognize that unless his signal is the maximum
he will receive a payoff of zero.
50Defining the Winners Curse
- The winner's curse can be defined as
- W(sn) Evnsn - Evn sn maxs1,,sN
- Since the max operator is a convex increasing
function of its arguments - it follows that W(sn) is a negative function.
- Although bidders should take the winner's curse
into account, there is widespread evidence that
novice bidders do not take this extra information
into account when placing a bid.
51Revenue Comparisons forSymmetric Auctions
- We can rank the expected revenue generated in
symmetric equilibrium for auctions where
valuations are also symmetric. - There are two basic results. In a symmetric
auction - 1. The expected revenue from a Japanese auction
is higher than what an English auction yields. - 2. The expected revenue from an English auction
exceeds a first price sealed bid auction.
52Differential information
- We have discussed several types of information
structures in auctions - - perfect foresight
- - independently distributed private valuations
- - symmetric valuations.
- But one important case we have not touched yet,
when some bidders know more about the common
value of the object than other bidders do.
53Bidding with differential information
- An extreme form of dependent signals occurs when
one bidder know the signal and the others do not. - How should an informed player bid?
- What about an uninformed player?
54An English common value auction experiment on
asymmetrically informed bidders
55A sealed bid common value auction on
asymmetrically informed bidders
56Perspective of the less informed bidder
- Suppose the uninformed bidder always makes the
same positive bid, denoted b. This is an example
of a pure strategy. - Is this pure strategy part of a Nash
equilibrium? - The best response of the informed bidder is to
bid a little more than b when the value of the
object vi is worth more than b, and less than b
otherwise. - Therefore the uninformed bidder makes an
expected loss by playing a pure strategy in this
auction. A better strategy would be to bid
nothing.
57A theorem
- The argument in the previous slide shows that
the uninformed bidder plays a mixed strategy in
this game. - One can show that in equilibrium the informed
bidder bids according to the strategy - ?(x) EVV ? x
- and that the uninformed bidder chooses a bid at
random from the interval 0, EV according to
the probability distribution H defined by - H(b) Prob?(V) ? b
58The field of bidders
- The last part of this lecture discusses two
issues outside the bidding process itself that
nevertheless may affect the outcome of the
auction. - They are
- Collusion amongst bidders
- Determining the number of bidders
- The degree of collusion and entry deterrence may
affect how the auctioneer and the bidders rank
different types of auctions that are revenue
equivalent, or even strategically equivalent.
59Collusion
- First we discuss the scope for collusive
behavior under different auction mechanisms. - Collusion between bidders is only possible if
there is a mechanism for determining within a
designated bidding ring which bidder has the
highest valuation, and then ensuring members of
the ring do not break the collusive agreement in
the bidding. - We focus on the second point. Sometimes
determining which member has the highest
valuation is trivial (for example in common value
auctions), and sometimes it can be resolved
through an auction within the ring for the right
to present the only serious bid to the
auctioneer.
60Evidence about collusion in auctions
- Section 1 of the Sherman Act pertains to trusts
and illegal constraints to trade. - Over three quarters of the criminal cases filed
in the 1980s under its provisions were in
auctions markets. - Given the difficulty in finding sufficient
grounds to prosecute this illegal activity, one
can safely conclude that collusive behavior in
auctions is often a serious concern for the
seller.
61What are the gains from collusive behavior?
- Consider a bidding ring of R members out of a
total of N bidders. - The goal of the ring is to internally solve
which of the players have the highest valuation,
and then make one (serious) bid instead of R
bids. - With fewer effective bidders in the auction,
the expected price of the object is lower. - If all the bidders are able to collude, meaning
N R, the auction reduces to a game of bilateral
bargaining between the auctioneer and the single
bidder.
62Bidding rings in second price sealed bid auctions
- For example, suppose the player with the
highest valuation in the ring bids it, the other
bidders in the ring submit the auctioneers
reservation price, and the bidders outside the
ring respond optimally but individually by
bidding their true valuations. - Then the ring benefits from colluding if
- 1. The high bid from the ring wins the auction
- 2. The second highest valuation of bidders in
the ring exceeds the highest valuation of all
the bidders outside the ring.
63Enforcing collusion in first and second price
sealed bid auctions
- One reason why second price auctions are rarely
used in practice is because they are more
susceptible to collusion. - In a first price sealed bid auction, a member
of the bidding ring must submit a bid over the
rings low price to win the auction. Providing
his valuation exceeds the rings bid, there is an
opportunity to make profits by deviating from the
rings decision. This makes collusive bidding
harder to enforce. - Contrast this with a second price auction. In
order to win the auction a bidder in the ring who
breaks the collusive agreement must pay the
reported value of the ring. The agreement by the
ring is self enforcing!
64Ascending auctions encourage communication
amongst the bidders
- A key issue for firms attempting to collude is
agreeing how to share the spoils. - In a multiunit ascending auction, bidders can
use the early stages when prices are still low to
signal their views about who should win which
object, and then when consensus has been reached,
tacitly agree to stop pushing prices up. - By contrast, bidders cannot easily achieve the
same coordination in simultaneous sealed-bid or
descending auctions, in which each player
simultaneously makes at most a single best and
final offer to each object.
65Low reservation prices encourage collusion
- Reducing the reserve price increase the
potential gains from joint-bidding or colluding,
because the gains from colluding are greater. - Therefore the auctioneer should set a
reservation price that is higher than the
opportunity cost of failing to sell the auctioned
item if it reduces the probability that bidders
will collude.
66Entry and the provision of information about the
auctioned object
- Should the auctioneer encourage more players to
enter the auction? - Potential bidders could, for example, be
encouraged to bid in an auction, by providing
them with services that help them to value the
object for sale. - Note that simply paying people to participate in
the auction would not achieve any useful purpose,
because anyone could accept the payment and then
make a very low bid.
67Encouraging entry in private valuation auctions
- If another bidder enters a private valuation
auction, the the level of the highest or the
second highest valuation might increase. - In either case, the revenue from the auction
would increase. - Therefore the expected revenue from holding a
private valuation auction increases with the
number of bidders.
68Encouraging entry in common value auctions
- The argument for encouraging participation is
less definitive. - In an example discussed earlier we found that
the auctioneer gains from having a (second)
uninformed bidder enter the auction even though
the uninformed bidder is indifferent between
bidding or not. - However one can construct examples of common
value auctions in which the winning bid falls as
the number of bidders increases.
69Encouraging entry to avoid collusion
- The lower the number of bidders, the easier it
is for them to reach a collusive agreement. - Thus another reason to encourage entry is to
reduce the probability for facing a bidding
cartel.
70Summary and Synthesis
- When comparing two (or more) auctions, we should
consider the following questions - Are the auctions congruent, or if not, revenue
equivalent? - Are the bidders risk neutral?
- In private valuation auctions, are bidders
drawing from the same probability distribution? - In common valuation auctions, are bidders drawing
from the same distribution of signals? - Are the auctions symmetric?
- Is collusion between bidders a possibility?
- Should information about the auction be given to
bidders? - Not all these questions have easy answers, but
that is where the value of experiments is
especially evident.