Title: Negligence and Custom outline, Oct. 12, 2004
1Negligence and Custom (outline, Oct. 12, 2004)
- Three possible standards a Goldilocks story
- Titus v. Bradford (too hard)
- Mayhew (too soft)
- The T.J. Hooper (just right)
- 2. Should custom control? (Pros
and Cons)
2Titus v. Ry. (p. 188)
- Reasonably safe means safe according to the
usages, habits, and ordinary risks of the
business. . . . The unbending test of negligence
in methods, machinery, and appliances is the
ordinary usage of the business. . . . The
standard of due care is the conduct of the
average prudent man.
3Mayhew v. Sullivan Mining (p. 190)
- If the defendants had proved that in every
mining establishment that has existed since the
days of Tubal-Cain, it has been the practice to
cut ladder holes in their platforms . . . without
guarding or lighting them and without notice . .
. it would have no tendency to show that the act
was consistent with ordinary prudence or a due
regard for the safety of those who were using
their premises by their invitation.
4The T.J. Hooper (p. 191)
- The District Court Compliance with custom is a
duty. - The Court of Appeals
- In most cases reasonable prudence is in fact
common prudence but strictly it is never its
measure a whole calling may have unduly lagged
in adoption of new and available devices. It
never may set its own tests, however persuasive
be its usages.
5Conditions for efficient operation of tort
standard
- Standard of care at least as demanding of
defendants as the Hand test (I.e., liability for
failure to take cost-effective precautionary
measures). - Stricter standard of care only if it is a
liability rule, not a conduct rule.
6Liability and precautions (review 10/5/04)
Efficient conduct by injurers
i ii iii iv v
(least strict) (most strict)
7Bargaining and Malpractice (outline for Oct.
14, 2004)
- Review of pros and cons of bargaining
- Medical Malpractice and custom
- The usual rule within the range of acceptable
alternatives (Lama v. Borras) - The locality issue (Brune v. Belinkoff)
- The alternative, cost-benefit analysis (Helling
v. Carey) - The special case of informed consent (Canterbury
v. Spence)
8Custom Pros and Cons
- Pro
- 1. Certainty (rule rather than standard)
promotes administrability, equal application,
lessened transaction costs. - 2. Bargaining, with all the benefits that entails
- 3. Harness expertise
- Con
- 1. Homogeneity
- 2. Self-dealing, because unequal bargaining
power, imperfect information, etc. - 3. Stifle (or fail to encourage) innovation
9Custom Pros and Cons
- Pro
- 1. Certainty (rule rather than standard)
promotes administrability, equal application,
lessened transaction costs. - 2. Bargaining, with all the benefits that entails
- 3. Harness expertise
- Con
- 1. Homogeneity
- 2. Self-dealing, because unequal bargaining
power, imperfect information, etc. - 3. Stifle (or fail to encourage) innovation
102. Bargaining Pros and Cons
- Pro Utilitarian arguments
- expertise of parties in what they want and need
- idiosyncratic valuation
- Allow Coasian bargaining (makes the choice of
legal rule less important) - Con Utilitarian arguments
- Inappropriate decisionmaking by parties
(inability to understand risks, inappropriate
devaluation of self-harm, etc.) - externalities from inequalities
- Imperfect markets unavailable information,
transaction costs etc.
11Coase and his contribution
- The Coase theorem
- The insight of mutual causation.
-
12 132. Bargaining Pros and Cons, b
- Pro Liberty arguments (liberty for its own
sake) - Con Equality arguments
- Unequal bargaining power/information (discontent
over allocation of bargaining surplus) - Default rule tends to favor the status quo
14Possible rules w/r/t custom
- Custom as mandatory term of contract.
- Reasonable care as mandatory term of contract.
- Custom as default term of contract
- Custom as available to parties if they expressly
bargain for it (so default term is externally
developed reasonable care)
15How to pick a default term
- Approximate what the parties are likely to
bargain for (decrease costs of reaching
agreement). (Serves utility) OR - Force better information, by picking something
the parties are NOT likely to bargain for,
requiring them to bargain around it. (Serves
liberty), OR - Distributional considerations. (Serves equality)
16Medical Malpractice
- Standard Within the range of acceptable
alternatives that is, customary practice.
17Medical Malpractice
- Why is custom the standard? The arguments
- 1) The practices of the profession make tort law
standard-setting less necessary. - Alternative institutions encourage
other-regarding behavior, innovation, training,
etc. - 2) Variety of factors make tort law less
accurate - Prevalence of bad outcomes.
- Technical difficulty of the subject matter.
18Canterbury v. Spence Informed Consent and Custom
- Respect for the patients right of
self-determination on particular therapy demands
a standard set by law for physicians rather than
one which physicians may or may not impose upon
themselves.
19Canterbury v. Spence Standard for Informed
Consent
- A. Scope of duty
- The test for determining whether a particular
peril must be divulged is its materiality to the
patients decision all risks potentially
affecting the decision must be unmasked.
20Canterbury v. Spence Standard for Informed
Consent
- B. Causation
- A causal connection exists when, but only when,
disclosure of significant risks incidental to
treatment would have resulted in a decision
against it. - The causation issue should be resolved . . .
On an objective basis in terms of what a prudent
person in the patients position would have
decided.
21Canterbury v. Spence Doctrinal mechanics The
informed consent two-step
- Breach the materiality standard.
- Causation But for causation.
- Subjective What would this patient have done
- Objective What would reasonable patient have
done.
22Malpractice (cont.) Statutes Presumptions
(class outline, Oct. 19, 2004)
- Medical Malpractice and custom (cont.)
- The special case of informed consent (Canterbury
v. Spence, mock argument) - The alternative, cost-benefit analysis (Helling
v. Carey) - Criminal or other regulatory laws, and statutory
causes of action (express and implied) - Statutes as a source of content for negligence
inquiry. - -- Osborne v. McMasters, Gorris v. Scott
23Canterbury v. Spence
- Why stray from normal reliance on custom for
informed consent? - Value choice priority of autonomy over
expertise. - Need for incentives absence of professional
norms that serve preferred value