Title: Market Structure In the Healthcare Industry
1Market Structure In the Healthcare Industry
- Professor Vivian Ho
- Health Economics
- Fall 2009
These notes draw from material in Santerre
Neun, Health Economics, Theories, Insights and
Industry Studies. Southwestern Cengate 2010
2Outline
- Defining perfect competition
- The market structure continuum
- Monopoly
- Monopolistic competition
- Oligopoly
- The market for organs
3Characteristics of Perfect Competition
- Consumers pay the full price of the product
- Consumers will respond to differences in prices
among sellers - All firms maximize profits
- Firms have incentives to satisfy consumer wants
and produce efficiently
4Characteristics of Perfect Competition (cont.)
- There is a large number of buyers and sellers,
each of which is small relative to the total
market - No one buyer or seller is powerful enough to
influence or manipulate the market price of a
product - All firms in the same industry produce a
homogeneous product - A consumer can easily find substitutes for the
product of any given firm
5Characteristics of Perfect Competition (cont.)
- No barriers to entry or exit exist
- New firms can enter the industry
- All economic agents possess perfect information
- Consumers and firms can make informed choices
- All firms face nondecreasing average costs of
production - Rules out a natural monopoly
6Monopoly Model
- In contrast to perfect competition, a monopoly
market has the following features - One seller
- Homogeneous or differentiated product
- Complete barriers to entry
- Because there is only one firm, that firm faces
the market demand curve, which is downward sloping
7Monopoly Model (cont.)
- What is the profit-maximizing price and quantity
for a monopolist? - Recall that all firms will maximize profits where
MRMC - We have already seen that the marginal cost curve
for a firm depends on its production function and
input prices - What does the firms MR curve look like?
8Monopoly Model (cont.)
- MR P Q (?P/?Q)
- Because the second term in this formula
represents a revenue loss, it is always negative - Thus, at each level of output, marginal revenue
is always lower than price - The marginal revenue curve lies under the demand
curve
9Monopoly Model (cont.)
Dollars per unit
Demand
MR
Quantity
10Monopoly Model (cont.)
- We are now ready to find the profit-maximizing
output for a monopolist - The monopolist sets output at a level where MRMC
- On a graph, find the level of Q where the MR and
MC curves intersect - To determine the price the monopolist will
charge, locate the price on the demand curve at
this same output level
11Monopoly Model (cont.)
Dollars per unit
MC
P
Demand
MR
Q
Quantity
12Monopoly Model (cont.)
- The monopolists level of profits can then be
determined by adding its average total cost curve
to the graph - Profits will be the difference between P and
ATC, multiplied by Q
13Monopoly Model (cont.)
Dollars per unit
MC
P
ATC
Profits
ATC
Demand
MR
Q
Quantity
14Contrast to Perfect Competition
Dollars per unit
Under perfect competition, the market equilibrium
would instead be where PMC
MC
ATC
PC
Demand
MR
QC
Quantity
The higher price and lower output in a
monopolized market is why economists claim that
competition is better for social welfare
15Monopoly Model (cont.)
- A monopoly only maintains its status if there are
no substitutes for the product it sells - There must be barriers to entry, so that other
firms cannot enter the market to compete - The two most common barriers to entry
- Economies of scale
- Legal restrictions
16Monopoly Model (cont.)
- Economies of scale
- If a monopoly is producing output at a level
where long run average costs are declining, then
new firms cannot compete on a cost basis - A monopoly hospital in a small town may have
substantial economies of scale if it can meet
demand with only 40-50 beds - Unless a new hospital could take away a
substantial share of the existing hospitals
patients, it could not match the existing
hospital in costs (and therefore profits as well)
17Monopoly Model (cont.)
- Legal restrictions
- Physicians require a license to practice medicine
- Many states require that providers obtain a
Certificate of Need to offer a new service - Drug companies obtain patents for new
pharmaceutical products
18The Market Structure Continuum
- We have talked about 2 extremes of the market
structure continuum - Perfect Competition
- Pure Monopoly
- Along this continuum, there are 2 more levels of
competitiveness that we will encounter in the
health care sector
19The Market Structure Continuum
Perfect Competition
Oligopoly
Monopoly
Monopolistic Competition
20Monopolistic Competition
- Many sellers
- Differentiated product
- No barriers to entry
- Examples
- Breakfast cereals
- Ibuprofen (Advil, Motrin, etc.)
- Cigarettes
21Monopolistic Competition (cont.)
- Because products are differentiated across firms,
each seller has some ability to control price - Each seller faces a slightly downward sloping
demand curve - Sellers have an incentive to differentiate
their product from competitors - Doing so is likely to raise demand for their
product
22Monopolistic Competition (cont.)
Dollars per Unit
Demand under monopolistic competition
Demand under perfect competition
Output
2 potential demand curves for an individual firm
23Monopolistic Competition (cont.)
- How do sellers differentiate their product?
- Advertising
- Is advertising bad for consumers?
- Creates imaginary or artificial wants
- Persuasive, not informative
- Business stealing, w/ no benefits to consumer
- Habit buying is a barrier to entry
24Monopolistic Competition (cont.)
- Benefits of advertising
- May convey important info on value of a good or
service - People benefit from real diversity choice
- Cheap info to customers to distinguish b/w
products - May promote quality competition
- Firms willing to invest in creating a brand name
reputation will work to keep it - May inform the consumer of good or service they
werent aware of - Shift the D curve out
25DTC Drug Advertising
- August 1997, FDA permitted brand-specific
direct-to-consumer (DTC) advertising w/o brief
summary of drug effectiveness, side effects, and
contraindications - DTC advertising rose from 800m in 1996 to 2.5b
in 2000 - What were the consequences?
- (Iizuka Jin, 2003)
26DTC Drug Advertising
- Iizuka Jin track monthly expenditures on DTC
advertising for 1994-2000 - They also track monthly visits to the doctor in a
recurring national survey for 1994-2000 - Survey indicates whether a drug was prescribed
during the visit, and for what class
27DTC Drug Advertising
- Classes of drugs w/ heavy advertising had large ?
in prescribing
28DTC Drug Advertising
- Classes of drugs w/ less advertising had no ?in
prescriptions
29DTC Drug Advertising
- IV column After deregulation, each 1 ? in DTC
Ads raises of visits w/ a prescription by .0464
30DTC Drug Advertising
- IV column After deregulation, each 1 ? in DTC
Ads raises of visits w/ a prescription by .0464 - How much ad spending is needed to get one extra
prescription? - 1/.046421.55
- Does DTC advertising look profitable to drug
companies?
31Oligopoly
- Few, dominant sellers
- Homogeneous or differentiated product
- Substantial barriers to entry
- Examples
- Tertiary services at teaching hospitals
- Many prescription drugs
32Oligopoly
- Because there are only a few dominant sellers,
actions of any one firm can change the overall
market price - Like monopoly, oligopoly will lead to lower
output and higher prices than would be observed
under perfect competition - Regulators are concerned about consumer welfare
in oligopolistic markets
33Markets for Organs
- Should we allow markets for organs for transplant
surgery? - Payment to donors of organs is currently
forbidden in developed countries. - Yet there is persistent excess demand for organ
transplants (Becker and Elias, JEP 2007)
34Markets for Organs
35Markets for Organs
36Markets for Organs
- Estimate excess demand from the growth in the
waiting list in any year, plus deaths for those
on waiting list. - Excess demand in kidney market grew from 2,500
persons in 1991 to 7,000 in 2000.
37The Price of an Organ
- How much pay is required to induce an individual
to sell an organ? - Compensate individual for
- Risk of death
- Time lost during recovery
- Risk of reduced quality of life
38Pricing Risk of Death
- risk of death x Value of a statistical life
- Estimated range 1.5 - 10 m for someone with a
35,000 average annual income in 2005. - Risk of death .1
- e.g. 5 m x .1 5,000
39Time Lost During Recovery
- Assume donor earns 35,000 / year
- Loses 4 weeks of work while in recovery
- 35,000 x 4 weeks gt 2,700
40Risk of Quality of Life
- No comprehensive data on how kidney donation
affects QOL. - Some studies suggest kidney donors can live
normal lives, unless high physical contact (e.g.
athletes). - But other studies find kidney donors at high risk
of high blood pressure. - Could arbitrarily assume 7,500.
41Market for Organs
- Cost of Performing Kidney transplant surgery
160K - Risk of Death 5,000
- Time Lost in Recovery 2,700
- Risk of QOL 7,500
- 15,200
-
- Live donors raise total price 15,200 / 160,000
9.5, - but supply is perfectly elastic.
42Markets for Organs
- 13,500 kidney transplants in 2005,
- 8000 on waiting list
- gt excess demand 21,500
- Assume eD for organ transplants -1
- price 9.5 gt demand 9.5
- 9.5 x 21,500 2,043
- Demand 21,500 2043 19,457, but all would be
supplied. - Equilibrium transplants rise from 13,500 to
19,457 44
43Excess Demand if Sales are Banned
Excess Demand
D
Q0 Transplants
44Market for Organs
S
e
S
175,200
160,000
D
Q0 Q1 Transplants
45Markets for Organs
- Under a range of assumptions, allowing the sale
of live donor organs substantially raises the
of transplants. - See Table 3, Becker.